F.10 Would laissez-faire capitalism be stable?

Unsurprisingly, right-libertarians combine their support for "absolute property rights" with a whole-hearted support for laissez-faire capitalism. In such a system (which they maintain, to quote Ayn Rand, is an "unknown ideal") everything would be private property and there would be few (if any) restrictions on "voluntary exchanges." "Anarcho"-capitalists are the most extreme of defenders of pure capitalism, urging that the state itself be privatised and no voluntary exchange made illegal (for example, children would be considered the property of their parents and it would be morally right to turn them into child prostitutes -- the child has the option of leaving home if they object).

As there have been no example of "pure" capitalism it is difficult to say whether their claims about are true (for a discussion of a close approximation see the section F.10.3). This section of the FAQ is an attempt to discover whether such a system would be stable or whether it would be subject to the usual booms and slumps. Before starting we should note that there is some disagreement within the right-libertarian camp itself on this subject (although instead of stability they usually refer to "equilibrium" -- which is an economics term meaning that all of a societies resources are fully utilised).

In general terms, most right-Libertarians' reject the concept of equilibrium as such and instead stress that the economy is inherently a dynamic (this is a key aspect of the Austrian school of economics). Such a position is correct, of course, as such noted socialists as Karl Marx and Michal Kalecki and capitalist economists as Keynes recognised long ago. There seems to be two main schools of thought on the nature of disequilibrium. One, inspired by von Mises, maintains that the actions of the entrepreneur/capitalist results in the market co-ordinating supply and demand and another, inspired by Joseph Schumpeter, who question whether markets co-ordinate because entrepreneurs are constantly innovating and creating new markets, products and techniques.

Of course both actions happen and we suspect that the differences in the two approaches are not important. The important thing to remember is that "anarcho"-capitalists and right-libertarians in general reject the notion of equilibrium -- but when discussing their utopia they do not actually indicate this! For example, most "anarcho"-capitalists will maintain that the existence of government (and/or unions) causes unemployment by either stopping capitalists investing in new lines of industry or forcing up the price of labour above its market clearing level (by, perhaps, restricting immigration, minimum wages, taxing profits). Thus, we are assured, the worker will be better off in "pure" capitalism because of the unprecedented demand for labour it will create. However, full employment of labour is an equilibrium in economic terms and that, remember, is impossible due to the dynamic nature of the system. When pressed, they will usually admit there will be periods of unemployment as the market adjusts or that full unemployment actually means under a certain percentage of unemployment. Thus, if you (rightly) reject the notion of equilibrium you also reject the idea of full employment and so the labour market becomes a buyers market and labour is at a massive disadvantage.

The right-libertarian case is based upon logical deduction, and the premises required to show that laissez-faire will be stable are somewhat incredible. If banks do not set the wrong interest rate, if companies do not extend too much trade credit, if workers are willing to accept (real wage related) pay cuts, if workers altruistically do not abuse their market power in a fully employed society, if interest rates provide the correct information, if capitalists predict the future relatively well, if banks and companies do not suffer from isolation paradoxes, then, perhaps, laissez-faire will be stable.

So, will laissez-faire capitalism be stable? Let us see by analysing the assumptions of right-libertarianism -- namely that there will be full employment and that a system of private banks will stop the business cycle. We will start on the banking system first (in section F.10.1) followed by the effects of the labour market on economic stability (in section F.10.2). Then we will indicate, using the example of 19th century America, that actually existing ("impure") laissez-faire was very unstable.

Explaining booms and busts by state action plays an ideological convenience as it exonerates market processes as the source of instability within capitalism. We hope to indicate in the next two sections why the business cycle is inherent in the system (see also sections C.7, C.8 and C.9).

F.10.1 Would privatising banking make capitalism stable?

It is claimed that the existence of the state (or, for minimal statists, government policy) is the cause of the business cycle (recurring economic booms and slumps). This is because the government either sets interest rates too low or expands the money supply (usually by easing credit restrictions and lending rates, sometimes by just printing fiat money). This artificially increases investment as capitalists take advantage of the artificially low interest rates. The real balance between savings and investment is broken, leading to over-investment, a drop in the rate of profit and so a slump (which is quite socialist in a way, as many socialists also see over-investment as the key to understanding the business cycle, although they obviously attribute the slump to different causes -- namely the nature of capitalist production, not that the credit system does not play its part -- see section C.7).

In the words of Austrian Economist W. Duncan Reekie, "[t]he business cycle is generated by monetary expansion and contraction . . . When new money is printed it appears as if the supply of savings has increased. Interest rates fall and businessmen are misled into borrowing additional founds to finance extra investment activity . . . This would be of no consequence if it had been the outcome of [genuine saving] . . . -but the change was government induced. The new money reaches factor owners in the form of wages, rent and interest . . . the factor owners will then spend the higher money incomes in their existing consumption:investment proportions . . . Capital goods industries will find their expansion has been in error and malinvestments have been inoccured." [Markets, Entrepreneurs and Liberty, pp. 68-9]

In other words, there has been "wasteful mis-investment due to government interference with the market." [Op. Cit., p. 69] In response to this (negative) influence in the workings of the market, it is suggested by right-libertarians that a system of private banks should be used and that interest rates are set by them, via market forces. In this way an interest rate that matches the demand and supply for savings will be reached and the business cycle will be no more. By truly privatising the credit market, it is hoped by the business cycle will finally stop.

Unsurprisingly, this particular argument has its weak points and in this section of the FAQ we will try to show exactly why this theory is wrong.

Let us start with Reckie's starting point. He states that the "main problem" of the slump is "why is there suddenly a 'cluster' of business errors? Businessmen and entrepreneurs are market experts (otherwise they would not survive) and why should they all make mistakes simultaneously?" [Op. Cit., p. 68] It is this "cluster" of mistakes that the Austrians' take as evidence that the business cycle comes from outside the workings of the market (i.e. is exogenous in nature). Reekie argues that an "error cluster only occurs when all entrepreneurs have received the wrong signals on potential profitability, and all have received the signals simultaneously through government interference with the money supply." [Op. Cit., p. 74] But is this really the case?

The simple fact is that groups of (rational) individuals can act in the same way based on the same information and this can lead to a collective problem. For example, we do not consider it irrational that everyone in a building leaves it when the fire alarm goes off and that the flow of people can cause hold-ups at exits. Neither do we think that its unusual that traffic jams occur, after all those involved are all trying to get to work (i.e. they are reacting to the same desire). Now, is it so strange to think that capitalists who all see the same opportunity for profit in a specific market decide to invest in it? Or that the aggregate outcome of these individually rational decisions may be irrational (i.e. cause a glut in the market)?

In other words, a "cluster" of business failures may come about because a group of capitalists, acting in isolation, over-invest in a given market. They react to the same information (namely super profits in market X), arrange loans, invest and produce commodities to meet demand in that market. However, the aggregate result of these individually rational actions is that the aggregate supply far exceeds demand, causing a slump in that market and, perhaps, business failures. The slump in this market (and the potential failure of some firms) has an impact on the companies that supplied them, the companies that are dependent on their employees wages/demand, the banks that supplied the credit and so forth. The accumulative impact of this slump (or failures) on the chain of financial commitments of which they are but one link can be large and, perhaps, push an economy into general depression. Thus the claim that it is something external to the system that causes depression is flawed.

It could be claimed the interest rate is the problem, that it does not accurately reflect the demand for investment or relate it to the supply of savings. But, as we argued in section C.8, it is not at all clear that the interest rate provides the necessary information to capitalists. They need investment information for their specific industry, but the interest rate is cross-industry. Thus capitalists in market X do not know if the investment in market X is increasing and so this lack of information can easily cause "mal-investment" as over-investment (and so over-production) occurs. As they have no way of knowing what the investment decisions of their competitors are or now these decisions will affect an already unknown future, capitalists may over-invest in certain markets and the net effects of this aggregate mistake can expand throughout the whole economy and cause a general slump. In other words, a cluster of business failures can be accounted for by the workings of the market itself and not the (existence of) government.

This is one possible reason for an internally generated business cycle but that is not the only one. Another is the role of class struggle which we discuss in the next section and yet another is the endogenous nature of the money supply itself. This account of money (proposed strongly by, among others, the post-Keynesian school) argues that the money supply is a function of the demand for credit, which itself is a function of the level of economic activity. In other words, the banking system creates as much money as people need and any attempt to control that creation will cause economic problems and, perhaps, crisis (interestingly, this analysis has strong parallels with mutualist and individualist anarchist theories on the causes of capitalist exploitation and the business cycle). Money, in other words, emerges from within the system and so the right-libertarian attempt to "blame the state" is simply wrong.

Thus what is termed "credit money" (created by banks) is an essential part of capitalism and would exist without a system of central banks. This is because money is created from within the system, in response to the needs of capitalists. In a word, money is endogenous and credit money an essential part of capitalism.

Right-libertarians do not agree. Reekie argues that "[o]nce fractional reserve banking is introduced, however, the supply of money substitutes will include fiduciary media. The ingenuity of bankers, other financial intermediaries and the endorsement and guaranteeing of their activities by governments and central banks has ensured that the quantity of fiat money is immense." [Op. Cit., p. 73]

Therefore, what "anarcho"-capitalists and other right-libertarians seem to be actually complaining about when they argue that "state action" creates the business cycle by creating excess money is that the state allows bankers to meet the demand for credit by creating it. This makes sense, for the first fallacy of this sort of claim is how could the state force bankers to expand credit by loaning more money than they have savings. And this seems to be the normal case within capitalism -- the central banks accommodate bankers activity, they do not force them to do it. Alan Holmes, a senior vice president at the New York Federal Reserve, stated that:

"In the real world, banks extend credit, creating deposits in the process, and look for the reserves later. The question then becomes one of whether and how the Federal Reserve will accommodate the demand for reserves. In the very short run, the Federal Reserve has little or no choice about accommodating that demand, over time, its influence can obviously be felt." [quoted by Doug Henwood, Wall Street, p. 220]

(Although we must stress that central banks are not passive and do have many tools for affecting the supply of money. For example, central banks can operate "tight" money policies which can have significant impact on an economy and, via creating high enough interest rates, the demand for money.)

It could be argued that because central banks exist, the state creates an "environment" which bankers take advantage off. By not being subject to "free market" pressures, bankers could be tempted to make more loans than they would otherwise in a "pure" capitalist system (i.e. create credit money). The question arises, would "pure" capitalism generate sufficient market controls to stop banks loaning in excess of available savings (i.e. eliminate the creation of credit money/fiduciary media).

It is to this question we now turn.

As noted above, the demand for credit is generated from within the system and the comments by Holmes reinforce this. Capitalists seek credit in order to make money and banks create it precisely because they are also seeking profit. What right-libertarians actually object to is the government (via the central bank) accommodating this creation of credit. If only the banks could be forced to maintain a savings to loans ration of one, then the business cycle would stop. But is this likely? Could market forces ensure that bankers pursue such a policy? We think not -- simply because the banks are profit making institutions. As post-Keynesianist Hyman Minsky argues, "[b]ecause bankers live in the same expectational climate as businessmen, profit-seeking bankers will find ways of accommodating their customers. . . Banks and bankers are not passive managers of money to lend or to invest; they are in business to maximise profits. . ." [quoted by L. Randall Wray, Money and Credit in Capitalist Economies, p. 85]

This is recognised by Reekie, in passing at least (he notes that "fiduciary media could still exist if bankers offered them and clients accepted them" [Op. Cit., p. 73]). Bankers will tend to try and accommodate their customers and earn as much money as possible. Thus Charles P. Kindleberger comments that monetary expansion "is systematic and endogenous rather than random and exogenous" seem to fit far better the reality of capitalism that the Austrian and right-libertarian viewpoint [Manias, Panics, and Crashes, p. 59] and post-Keynesian L. Randall Wray argues that "the money supply . . . is more obviously endogenous in the monetary systems which predate the development of a central bank." [Op. Cit., p. 150]

In other words, the money supply cannot be directly controlled by the central bank since it is determined by private decisions to enter into debt commitments to finance spending. Given that money is generated from within the system, can market forces ensure the non-expansion of credit (i.e. that the demand for loans equals the supply of savings)? To begin to answer this question we must note that investment is "essentially determined by expected profitability." [Philip Arestis, The Post-Keynesian Approach to Economics, p. 103] This means that the actions of the banks cannot be taken in isolation from the rest of the economy. Money, credit and banks are an essential part of the capitalist system and they cannot be artificially isolated from the expectations, pressures and influences of that system.

Let us assume that the banks desire to maintain a loans to savings ratio of one and try to adjust their interest rates accordingly. Firstly, changes in the rate of interest "produce only a very small, if any, movement in business investment" according to empirical evidence [Op. Cit., pp. 82-83] and that "the demand for credit is extremely inelastic with respect to interest rates." [L. Randall Wray, Op. Cit., p. 245] Thus, to keep the supply of savings in line with the demand for loans, interest rates would have to increase greatly (indeed, trying to control the money supply by controlling the monetary bases in this way will only lead to very big fluctuations in interest rates). And increasing interest rates has a couple of paradoxical effects.

According to economists Joseph Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss (in "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Knowledge", American Economic Review, no. 71, pp. 393-410) interest rates are subject to what is called the "lemons problem" (asymmetrical information between buyer and seller). Stiglitz and Weiss applied the "lemons problem" to the credit market and argued (and unknowingly repeated Adam Smith) that at a given interest rate, lenders will earn lower return by lending to bad borrowers (because of defaults) than to good ones. If lenders try to increase interest rates to compensate for this risk, they may chase away good borrowers, who are unwilling to pay a higher rate, while perversely not chasing away incompetent, criminal, or malignantly optimistic borrowers. This means that an increase in interest rates may actually increase the possibilities of crisis, as more loans may end up in the hands of defaulters.

This gives banks a strong incentive to keep interest rates lower than they otherwise could be. Moreover, "increases in interest rates make it more difficult for economic agents to meet their debt repayments" [Philip Arestis, Op. Cit., pp. 237-8] which means when interest rates are raised, defaults will increase and place pressures on the banking system. At high enough short-term interest rates, firms find it hard to pay their interest bills, which cause/increase cash flow problems and so "[s]harp increases in short term interest rates . . .leads to a fall in the present value of gross profits after taxes (quasi-rents) that capital assets are expected to earn." [Hyman Minsky, Post-Keynesian Economic Theory, p. 45]

In addition, "production of most investment goods is undertaken on order and requires time for completion. A rise in interest rates is not likely to cause firms to abandon projects in the process of production . . . This does not mean . . . that investment is completely unresponsive to interest rates. A large increase in interest rates causes a 'present value reversal', forcing the marginal efficiency of capital to fall below the interest rate. If the long term interest rate is also pushed above the marginal efficiency of capital, the project may be abandoned." [Wray, Op. Cit., pp. 172-3] In other words, investment takes time and there is a lag between investment decisions and actual fixed capital investment. So if interest rates vary during this lag period, initially profitable investments may become white elephants.

As Michal Kalecki argued, the rate of interest must be lower than the rate of profit otherwise investment becomes pointless. The incentive for a firm to own and operate capital is dependent on the prospective rate of profit on that capital relative to the rate of interest at which the firm can borrow at. The higher the interest rate, the less promising investment becomes.

If investment is unresponsive to all but very high interest rates (as we indicated above), then a privatised banking system will be under intense pressure to keep rates low enough to maintain a boom (by, perhaps, creating credit above the amount available as savings). And if it does this, over-investment and crisis is the eventual outcome. If it does not do this and increases interest rates then consumption and investment will dry up as interest rates rise and the defaulters (honest and dishonest) increase and a crisis will eventually occur.

This is because increasing interest rates may increase savings but it also reduce consumption ("high interest rates also deter both consumers and companies from spending, so that the domestic economy is weakened and unemployment rises" [Paul Ormerod, The Death of Economics, p. 70]). This means that firms can face a drop off in demand, causing them problems and (perhaps) leading to a lack of profits, debt repayment problems and failure. An increase in interest rates also reduces demand for investment goods, which also can cause firms problems, increase unemployment and so on. So an increase in interest rates (particularly a sharp rise) could reduce consumption and investment (i.e. reduce aggregate demand) and have a ripple effect throughout the economy which could cause a slump to occur.

In other words, interest rates and the supply and demand of savings/loans they are meant to reflect may not necessarily move an economy towards equilibrium (if such a concept is useful). Indeed, the workings of a "pure" banking system without credit money may increase unemployment as demand falls in both investment and consumption in response to high interest rates and a general shortage of money due to lack of (credit) money resulting from the "tight" money regime implied by such a regime (i.e. the business cycle would still exist). This was the case of the failed Monetarist experiments on the early 1980s when central banks in America and Britain tried to pursue a "tight" money policy. The "tight" money policy did not, in fact, control the money supply. All it did do was increase interest rates and lead to a serious financial crisis and a deep recession (as Wray notes, "the central bank uses tight money polices to raise interest rates" [Op. Cit., p. 262]). This recession, we must note, also broke the backbone of working class resistance and the unions in both countries due to the high levels of unemployment it generated. As intended, we are sure.

Such an outcome would not surprise anarchists, as this was a key feature of the Individualist and Mutualist Anarchists' arguments against the "money monopoly" associated with specie money. They argued that the "money monopoly" created a "tight" money regime which reduced the demand for labour by restricting money and credit and so allowed the exploitation of labour (i.e. encouraged wage labour) and stopped the development of non-capitalist forms of production. Thus Lysander Spooner's comments that workers need "money capital to enable them to buy the raw materials upon which to bestow their labour, the implements and machinery with which to labour . . . Unless they get this capital, they must all either work at a disadvantage, or not work at all. A very large portion of them, to save themselves from starvation, have no alternative but to sell their labour to others . . ." [A Letter to Grover Cleveland, p. 39] It is interesting to note that workers did do well during the 1950s and 1960s under a "liberal" money regime than they did under the "tighter" regimes of the 1980s and 1990s.

We should also note that an extended period of boom will encourage banks to make loans more freely. According to Minsky's "financial instability model" crisis (see "The Financial Instability Hypothesis" in Post-Keynesian Economic Theory for example) is essentially caused by risky financial practices during periods of financial tranquillity. In other words, "stability is destabilising." In a period of boom, banks are happy and the increased profits from companies are flowing into their vaults. Over time, bankers note that they can use a reserve system to increase their income and, due to the general upward swing of the economy, consider it safe to do so (and given that they are in competition with other banks, they may provide loans simply because they are afraid of losing customers to more flexible competitors). This increases the instability within the system (as firms increase their debts due to the flexibility of the banks) and produces the possibility of crisis if interest rates are increased (because the ability of business to fulfil their financial commitments embedded in debts deteriorates).

Even if we assume that interest rates do work as predicted in theory, it is false to maintain that there is one interest rate. This is not the case. "Concentration of capital leads to unequal access to investment funds, which obstructs further the possibility of smooth transitions in industrial activity. Because of their past record of profitability, large enterprises have higher credit ratings and easier access to credit facilities, and they are able to put up larger collateral for a loan." [Michael A. Bernstein, The Great Depression, p. 106] As we noted in section C.5.1, the larger the firm, the lower the interest rate they have to pay. Thus banks routinely lower their interest rates to their best clients even though the future is uncertain and past performance cannot and does not indicate future returns. Therefore it seems a bit strange to maintain that the interest rate will bring savings and loans into line if there are different rates being offered.

And, of course, private banks cannot affect the underlying fundamentals that drive the economy -- like productivity, working class power and political stability -- any more than central banks (although central banks can influence the speed and gentleness of adjustment to a crisis).

Indeed, given a period of full employment a system of private banks may actually speed up the coming of a slump. As we argue in the next section, full employment results in a profits squeeze as firms face a tight labour market (which drives up costs) and, therefore, increased workers' power at the point of production and in their power of exit. In a central bank system, capitalists can pass on these increasing costs to consumers and so maintain their profit margins for longer. This option is restricted in a private banking system as banks would be less inclined to devalue their money. This means that firms will face a profits squeeze sooner rather than later, which will cause a slump as firms cannot make ends meet. As Reekie notes, inflation "can temporarily reduce employment by postponing the time when misdirected labour will be laid off" but as Austrian's (like Monetarists) think "inflation is a monetary phenomenon" he does not understand the real causes of inflation and what they imply for a "pure" capitalist system [Op. Cit., p. 67, p. 74]. As Paul Ormerod points out "the claim that inflation is always and everywhere purely caused by increases in the money supply, and that there the rate of inflation bears a stable, predictable relationship to increases in the money supply is ridiculous." And he notes that "[i]ncreases in the rate of inflation tend to be linked to falls in unemployment, and vice versa" which indicates its real causes -- namely in the balance of class power and in the class struggle. [The Death of Economics, p. 96, p. 131]

Moreover, if we do take the Austrian theory of the business cycle at face value we are drawn to conclusion that in order to finance investment savings must be increased. But to maintain or increase the stock of loanable savings, inequality must be increased. This is because, unsurprisingly, rich people save a larger proportion of their income than poor people and the proportion of profits saved are higher than the proportion of wages. But increasing inequality (as we argued in section F.3.1) makes a mockery of right-libertarian claims that their system is based on freedom or justice.

This means that the preferred banking system of "anarcho"-capitalism implies increasing, not decreasing, inequality within society. Moreover, most firms (as we indicated in section C.5.1) fund their investments with their own savings which would make it hard for banks to loan these savings out as they could be withdrawn at any time. This could have serious implications for the economy, as banks refuse to fund new investment simply because of the uncertainty they face when accessing if their available savings can be loaned to others (after all, they can hardly loan out the savings of a customer who is likely to demand them at any time). And by refusing to fund new investment, a boom could falter and turn to slump as firms do not find the necessary orders to keep going.

So, would market forces create "sound banking"? The answer is probably not. The pressures on banks to make profits come into conflict with the need to maintain their savings to loans ration (and so the confidence of their customers). As Wray argues, "as banks are profit seeking firms, they find ways to increase their liabilities which don't entail increases in reserve requirements" and "[i]f banks share the profit expectations of prospective borrowers, they can create credit to allow [projects/investments] to proceed." [Op. Cit., p. 295, p. 283] This can be seen from the historical record. As Kindleberger notes, "the market will create new forms of money in periods of boom to get around the limit" imposed on the money supply [Op. Cit., p. 63]. Trade credit is one way, for example. Under the Monetarist experiments of 1980s, there was "deregulation and central bank constraints raised interest rates and created a moral hazard -- banks made increasingly risky loans to cover rising costs of issuing liabilities. Rising competition from nonbanks and tight money policy forced banks to lower standards and increase rates of growth in an attempt to 'grow their way to profitability'" [Op. Cit., p. 293]

Thus credit money ("fiduciary media") is an attempt to overcome the scarcity of money within capitalism, particularly the scarcity of specie money. The pressures that banks face within "actually existing" capitalism would still be faced under "pure" capitalism. It is likely (as Reekie acknowledges) that credit money would still be created in response to the demands of business people (although not at the same level as is currently the case, we imagine). The banks, seeking profits themselves and in competition for customers, would be caught between maintaining the value of their business (i.e. their money) and the needs to maximise profits. As a boom develops, banks would be tempted to introduce credit money to maintain it as increasing the interest rate would be difficult and potentially dangerous (for reasons we noted above). Thus, if credit money is not forth coming (i.e. the banks stick to the Austrian claims that loans must equal savings) then the rise in interest rates required will generate a slump. If it is forthcoming, then the danger of over-investment becomes increasingly likely. All in all, the business cycle is part of capitalism and not caused by "external" factors like the existence of government.

As Reekie notes, to Austrians "ignorance of the future is endemic" [Op. Cit., p. 117] but you would be forgiven for thinking that this is not the case when it comes to investment. An individual firm cannot know whether its investment project will generate the stream of returns necessary to meet the stream of payment commitments undertaken to finance the project. And neither can the banks who fund those projects. Even if a bank does not get tempted into providing credit money in excess of savings, it cannot predict whether other banks will do the same or whether the projects it funds will be successful. Firms, looking for credit, may turn to more flexible competitors (who practice reserve banking to some degree) and the inflexible bank may see its market share and profits decrease. After all, commercial banks "typically establish relations with customers to reduce the uncertainty involved in making loans. Once a bank has entered into a relationship with a customer, it has strong incentives to meet the demands of that customer." [Wray, Op. Cit., p. 85]

There are example of fully privatised banks. For example, in the United States "which was without a central bank after 1837" "the major banks in New York were in a bind between their roles as profit seekers, which made them contributors to the instability of credit, and as possessors of country deposits against whose instability they had to guard." [Kindleberger, Op. Cit., p. 85]

In Scotland, the banks were unregulated between 1772 and 1845 but "the leading commercial banks accumulated the notes of lessor ones, as the Second Bank of the United States did contemporaneously in [the USA], ready to convert them to specie if they thought they were getting out of line. They served, that is, as an informal controller of the money supply. For the rest, as so often, historical evidence runs against strong theory, as demonstrated by the country banks in England from 1745 to 1835, wildcat banking in Michigan in the 1830s, and the latest experience with bank deregulation in Latin America." [Op. Cit., p. 82] And we should note there were a few banking "wars" during the period of deregulation in Scotland which forced a few of the smaller banks to fail as the bigger ones refused their money and that there was a major bank failure in the Ayr Bank.

Kendleberger argues that central banking "arose to impose control on the instability of credit" and did not cause the instability which right-libertarians maintain it does. And as we note in section F.10.3, the USA suffered massive economic instability during its period without central banking. Thus, if credit money is the cause of the business cycle, it is likely that a "pure" capitalism will still suffer from it just as much as "actually existing" capitalism (either due to high interest rates or over-investment).

In general, as the failed Monetarist experiments of the 1980s prove, trying to control the money supply is impossible. The demand for money is dependent on the needs of the economy and any attempt to control it will fail (and cause a deep depression, usually via high interest rates). The business cycle, therefore, is an endogenous phenomenon caused by the normal functioning of the capitalist economic system. Austrian and right-libertarian claims that "slump flows boom, but for a totally unnecessary reason: government inspired mal-investment" [Reekie, Op. Cit., p. 74] are simply wrong. Over-investment does occur, but it is not "inspired" by the government. It is "inspired" by the banks need to make profits from loans and from businesses need for investment funds which the banks accommodate. In other words, by the nature of the capitalist system.

F.10.2 How does the labour market effect capitalism?

In many ways, the labour market is the one that affects capitalism the most. The right-libertarian assumption (like that of mainstream economics) is that markets clear and, therefore, the labour market will also clear. As this assumption has rarely been proven to be true in actuality (i.e. periods of full employment within capitalism are few and far between), this leaves its supporters with a problem -- reality contradicts the theory.

The theory predicts full employment but reality shows that this is not the case. Since we are dealing with logical deductions from assumptions, obviously the theory cannot be wrong and so we must identify external factors which cause the business cycle (and so unemployment). In this way attention is diverted away from the market and its workings -- after all, it is assumed that the capitalist market works -- and onto something else. This "something else" has been quite a few different things (most ridiculously, sun spots in the case of one of the founders of marginalist economics, William Stanley Jevons). However, these days most pro-free market capitalist economists and right-libertarians have now decided it is the state.

In this section of the FAQ we will present a case that maintains that the assumption that markets clear is false at least for one, unique, market -- namely, the market for labour. As the fundamental assumption underlying "free market" capitalism is false, the logically consistent superstructure built upon comes crashing down. Part of the reason why capitalism is unstable is due to the commodification of labour (i.e. people) and the problems this creates. The state itself can have positive and negative impacts on the economy, but removing it or its influence will not solve the business cycle.

Why is this? Simply due to the nature of the labour market.

Anarchists have long realised that the capitalist market is based upon inequalities and changes in power. Proudhon argued that "[t]he manufacturer says to the labourer, 'You are as free to go elsewhere with your services as I am to receive them. I offer you so much.' The merchant says to the customer, 'Take it or leave it; you are master of your money, as I am of my goods. I want so much.' Who will yield? The weaker." He, like all anarchists, saw that domination, oppression and exploitation flow from inequalities of market/economic power and that the "power of invasion lies in superior strength." [What is Property?, p. 216, p. 215]

This applies with greatest force to the labour market. While mainstream economics and right-libertarian variations of it refuse to acknowledge that the capitalist market is a based upon hierarchy and power, anarchists (and other socialists) do not share this opinion. And because they do not share this understanding with anarchists, right-libertarians will never be able to understand capitalism or its dynamics and development. Thus, when it comes to the labour market, it is essential to remember that the balance of power within it is the key to understanding the business cycle. Thus the economy must be understood as a system of power.

So how does the labour market effect capitalism? Let us consider a growing economy, on that is coming out of a recession. Such a growing economy stimulates demand for employment and as unemployment falls, the costs of finding workers increase and wage and condition demands of existing workers intensify. As the economy is growing and labour is scare, the threat associated with the hardship of unemployment is weakened. The share of profits is squeezed and in reaction to this companies begin to cut costs (by reducing inventories, postponing investment plans and laying off workers). As a result, the economy moves into a downturn. Unemployment rises and wage demands are moderated. Eventually, this enables the share of profits first of all to stabilise, and then rise. Such an "interplay between profits and unemployment as the key determinant of business cycles" is "observed in the empirical data." [Paul Ormerod, The Death of Economics, p. 188]

Thus, as an economy approaches full employment the balance of power on the labour market changes. The sack is no longer that great a threat as people see that they can get a job elsewhere easily. Thus wages and working conditions increase as companies try to get new (and keep) existing employees and output is harder to maintain. In the words of economist William Lazonick, labour "that is able to command a higher price than previously because of the appearance of tighter labour markets is, by definition, labour that is highly mobile via the market. And labour that is highly mobile via the market is labour whose supply of effort is difficult for managers to control in the production process. Hence, the advent of tight labour markets generally results in more rapidly rising average costs . . .as well as upward shifts in the average cost curve. . ." [Business Organisation and the Myth of the Market Economy, p. 106]

In other words, under conditions of full-employment "employers are in danger of losing the upper hand." [Juliet B. Schor, The Overworked American, p. 75] Schor argues that "employers have a structural advantage in the labour market, because there are typically more candidates ready and willing to endure this work marathon [of long hours] than jobs for them to fill." [p. 71] Thus the labour market is usually a buyers market, and so the sellers have to compromise. In the end, workers adapt to this inequality of power and instead of getting what they want, they want what they get.

But under full employment this changes. As we argued in section B.4.4 and section C.7, in such a situation it is the bosses who have to start compromising. And they do not like it. As Schor notes, America "has never experienced a sustained period of full employment. The closest we have gotten is the late 1960s, when the overall unemployment rate was under 4 percent for four years. But that experience does more to prove the point than any other example. The trauma caused to business by those years of a tight labour market was considerable. Since then, there has been a powerful consensus that the nation cannot withstand such a low rate of unemployment." [Op. Cit., pp. 75-76]

So, in other words, full employment is not good for the capitalist system due to the power full employment provides workers. Thus unemployment is a necessary requirement for a successful capitalist economy and not some kind of aberration in an otherwise healthy system. Thus "anarcho"-capitalist claims that "pure" capitalism will soon result in permanent full employment are false. Any moves towards full employment will result in a slump as capitalists see their profits squeezed from below by either collective class struggle or by individual mobility in the labour market.

This was recognised by Individualist Anarchists like Benjamin Tucker, who argued that mutual banking would "give an unheard of impetus to business, and consequently create an unprecedented demand for labour, -- a demand which would always be in excess of the supply, directly contrary of the present condition of the labour market." [The Anarchist Reader, pp. 149-150] In other words, full employment would end capitalist exploitation, drive non-labour income to zero and ensure the worker the full value of her labour -- in other words, end capitalism. Thus, for most (if not all) anarchists the exploitation of labour is only possible when unemployment exists and the supply of labour exceeds the demand for it. Any move towards unemployment will result in a profits squeeze and either the end of capitalism or an economic slump.

Indeed, as we argued in the last section, the extended periods of (approximately) full employment until the 1960s had the advantage that any profit squeeze could (in the short run anyway) be passed onto working class people in the shape of inflation. As prices rise, labour is made cheaper and profits margins supported. This option is restricted under a "pure" capitalism (for reasons we discussed in the last section) and so "pure" capitalism will be affected by full employment faster than "impure" capitalism.

As an economy approaches full employment, "hiring new workers suddenly becomes much more difficult. They are harder to find, cost more, and are less experiences. Such shortages are extremely costly for a firm." [Schor, Op. Cit., p. 75] This encourages a firm to pass on these rises to society in the form of price rises, so creating inflation. Workers, in turn, try to maintain their standard of living. "Every general increase in labour costs in recent years," note J. Brecher and J. Costello in the late 1970s, "has followed, rather than preceded, an increase in consumer prices. Wage increases have been the result of workers' efforts to catch up after their incomes have already been eroded by inflation. Nor could it easily be otherwise. All a businessman has to do to raise a price . . . [is to] make an announcement. . . Wage rates . . . are primarily determined by contracts" and so cannot be easily adjusted in the short term. [Common Sense for Bad Times, p, 120]

These full employment pressures will still exist with "pure" capitalism (and due to the nature of the banking system will not have the safety value of inflation). This means that periodic profit squeezes will occur, due to the nature of a tight labour market and the increased power of workers this generates. This in turn means that a "pure" capitalism will be subject to periods of unemployment (as we argued in section C.9) and so still have a business cycle. This is usually acknowledged by right-libertarians in passing, although they seem to think that this is purely a "short-term" problem (it seems a strange "short-term" problem that continually occurs).

But such an analysis is denied by right-libertarians. For them government action, combined with the habit of many labour unions to obtain higher than market wage rates for their members, creates and exacerbates mass unemployment. This flows from the deductive logic of much capitalist economics. The basic assumption of capitalism is that markets clear. So if unemployment exists then it can only be because the price of labour (wages) is too high (Austrian Economist W. Duncan Reekie argues that unemployment will "disappear provided real wages are not artificially high" [Markets, Entrepreneurs and Liberty, p. 72]).

Thus the assumption provokes the conclusion -- unemployment is caused by an unclearing market as markets always clear. And the cause for this is either the state or unions. But what if the labour market cannot clear without seriously damaging the power and profits of capitalists? What if unemployment is required to maximise profits by weakening labours' bargaining position on the market and so maximising the capitalists power? In that case unemployment is caused by capitalism, not by forces external to it.

However, let us assume that the right-libertarian theory is correct. Let us assume that unemployment is all the fault of the selfish unions and that a job-seeker "who does not want to wait will always get a job in the unhampered market economy." [von Mises, Human Action, p. 595]

Would crushing the unions reduce unemployment? Let us assume that the unions have been crushed and government has been abolished (or, at the very least, become a minimum state). The aim of the capitalist class is to maximise their profits and to do this they invest in labour saving machinery and otherwise attempt to increase productivity. But increasing productivity means that the prices of goods fall and falling prices mean increasing real wages. It is high real wages that, according to right-libertarians, that cause unemployment. So as a reward for increasing productivity, workers will have to have their money wages cut in order to stop unemployment occurring! For this reason some employers might refrain from cutting wages in order to avoid damage to morale - potentially an important concern.

Moreover, wage contracts involve time -- a contract will usually agree a certain wage for a certain period. This builds in rigidity into the market, wages cannot be adjusted as quickly as other commodity prices. Of course, it could be argued that reducing the period of the contract and/or allowing the wage to be adjusted could overcome this problem. However, if we reduce the period of the contract then workers are at a suffer disadvantage as they will not know if they have a job tomorrow and so they will not be able to easily plan their future (an evil situation for anyone to be in). Moreover, even without formal contracts, wage renegotiation can be expensive. After all, it takes time to bargain (and time is money under capitalism) and wage cutting can involve the risk of the loss of mutual good will between employer and employee. And would you give your boss the power to "adjust" your wages as he/she thought was necessary? To do so would imply an altruistic trust in others not to abuse their power.

Thus a "pure" capitalism would be constantly seeing employment increase and decrease as productivity levels change. There exist important reasons why the labour market need not clear which revolve around the avoidance/delaying of wage cuts by the actions of capitalists themselves. Thus, given a choice between cutting wages for all workers and laying off some workers without cutting the wages of the remaining employees, it is unsurprising that capitalists usually go for the later. After all, the sack is an important disciplining device and firing workers can make the remaining employees more inclined to work harder and be more obedient.

And, of course, many employers are not inclined to hire over-qualified workers. This is because, once the economy picks up again, their worker has a tendency to move elsewhere and so it can cost them time and money finding a replacement and training them. This means that involuntary unemployment can easily occur, so reducing tendencies towards full employment even more. In addition, one of the assumptions of the standard marginalist economic model is one of decreasing returns to scale. This means that as employment increases, costs rise and so prices also rise (and so real wages fall). But in reality many industries have increasing returns to scale, which means that as production increases unit costs fall, prices fall and so real wages rise. Thus in such an economy unemployment would increase simply because of the nature of the production process!

Moreover, as we argued in-depth in section C.9, a cut in money wages is not a neutral act. A cut in money wages means a reduction in demand for certain industries, which may have to reduce the wages of its employees (or fire them) to make ends meet. This could produce a accumulative effect and actually increase unemployment rather than reduce it.

In addition, there are no "self-correcting" forces at work in the labour market which will quickly bring employment back to full levels. This is for a few reasons. Firstly, the supply of labour cannot be reduced by cutting back production as in other markets. All we can do is move to other areas and hope to find work there. Secondly, the supply of labour can sometimes adjust to wage decreases in the wrong direction. Low wages might drive workers to offer a greater amount of labour (i.e. longer hours) to make up for any short fall (or to keep their job). This is usually termed the "efficiency wage" effect. Similarly, another family member may seek employment in order to maintain a given standard of living. Falling wages may cause the number of workers seeking employment to increase, causing a full further fall in wages and so on (and this is ignoring the effects of lowering wages on demand discussed in section C.9).

The paradox of piece work is an important example of this effect. As Schor argues, "piece-rate workers were caught in a viscous downward spiral of poverty and overwork. . . When rates were low, they found themselves compelled to make up in extra output what they were losing on each piece. But the extra output produced glutted the market and drove rates down further." [Juliet C. Schor, The Overworked American, p, 58]

Thus, in the face of reducing wages, the labour market may see an accumulative move away from (rather than towards) full employment, The right-libertarian argument is that unemployment is caused by real wages being too high which in turn flows from the assumption that markets clear. If there is unemployment, then the price of the commodity labour is too high -- otherwise supply and demand would meet and the market clear. But if, as we argued above, unemployment is essential to discipline workers then the labour market cannot clear except for short periods. If the labour market clears, profits are squeezed. Thus the claim that unemployment is caused by "too high" real wages is false (and as we argue in section C.9, cutting these wages will result in deepening any slump and making recovery longer to come about).

In other words, the assumption that the labour market must clear is false, as is any assumption that reducing wages will tend to push the economy quickly back to full employment. The nature of wage labour and the "commodity" being sold (i.e. human labour/time/liberty) ensure that it can never be the same as others. This has important implications for economic theory and the claims of right-libertarians, implications that they fail to see due to their vision of labour as a commodity like any other.

The question arises, of course, of whether, during periods of full employment, workers could not take advantage of their market power and gain increased workers' control, create co-operatives and so reform away capitalism. This was the argument of the Mutualist and Individualist anarchists and it does have its merits. However, it is clear (see section J.5.12) that bosses hate to have their authority reduced and so combat workers' control whenever they can. The logic is simple, if workers increase their control within the workplace the manager and bosses may soon be out of a job and (more importantly) they may start to control the allocation of profits. Any increase in working class militancy may provoke capitalists to stop/reduce investment and credit and so create the economic environment (i.e. increasing unemployment) necessary to undercut working class power.

In other words, a period of full unemployment is not sufficient to reform capitalism away. Full employment (nevermind any struggle over workers' control) will reduce profits and if profits are reduced then firms find it hard to repay debts, fund investment and provide profits for shareholders. This profits squeeze would be enough to force capitalism into a slump and any attempts at gaining workers' self-management in periods of high employment will help push it over the edge (after all, workers' control without control over the allocation of any surplus is distinctly phoney). Moreover, even if we ignore the effects of full employment may not last due to problems associated with over-investment (see section C.7.2), credit and interest rate problems (see section F.10.1) and realisation/aggregate demand disjoints. Full employment adds to the problems associated with the capitalist business cycle and so, if class struggle and workers power did not exist or cost problem, capitalism would still not be stable.

If equilibrium is a myth, then so is full employment. It seems somewhat ironic that "anarcho"-capitalists and other right-libertarians maintain that there will be equilibrium (full employment) in the one market within capitalism it can never actually exist in! This is usually quietly acknowledged by most right-libertarians, who mention in passing that some "temporary" unemployment will exist in their system -- but "temporary" unemployment is not full employment. Of course, you could maintain that all unemployment is "voluntary" and get round the problem by denying it, but that will not get us very far.

So it is all fine and well saying that "libertarian" capitalism would be based upon the maxim "From each as they choose, to each as they are chosen." [Robert Nozick, Anarchy, State, and Utopia, p. 160] But if the labour market is such that workers have little option about what they "choose" to give and fear that they will not be chosen, then they are at a disadvantage when compared to their bosses and so "consent" to being treated as a resource from the capitalist can make a profit from. And so this will result in any "free" contract on the labour market favouring one party at the expense of the other -- as can be seen from "actually existing capitalism".

Thus any "free exchange" on the labour market will usually not reflect the true desires of working people (and who will make all the "adjusting" and end up wanting what they get). Only when the economy is approaching full employment will the labour market start to reflect the true desires of working people and their wage start to approach its full product. And when this happens, profits are squeezed and capitalism goes into slump and the resulting unemployment disciplines the working class and restores profit margins. Thus full employment will be the exception rather than the rule within capitalism (and that is a conclusion which the historical record indicates).

In other words, in a normally working capitalist economy any labour contracts will not create relationships based upon freedom due to the inequalities in power between workers and capitalists. Instead, any contracts will be based upon domination, not freedom. Which prompts the question, how is libertarian capitalism libertarian if it erodes the liberty of a large class of people?

F.10.3 Was laissez-faire capitalism stable?

Firstly, we must state that a pure laissez-faire capitalist system has not existed. This means that any evidence we present in this section can be dismissed by right-libertarians for precisely this fact -- it was not "pure" enough. Of course, if they were consistent, you would expect them to shun all historical and current examples of capitalism or activity within capitalism, but this they do not. The logic is simple -- if X is good, then it is permissible to use it. If X is bad, the system is not pure enough.

However, as right-libertarians do use historical examples so shall we. According to Murray Rothbard, there was "quasi-laissez-faire industrialisation [in] the nineteenth century" [The Ethics of Liberty, p. 264] and so we will use the example of nineteenth century America -- as this is usually taken as being the closest to pure laissez-faire -- in order to see if laissez-faire is stable or not.

Yes, we are well aware that 19th century USA was far from laissez-faire -- there was a state, protectionism, government economic activity and so on -- but as this example has been often used by right-Libertarians' themselves (for example, Ayn Rand) we think that we can gain a lot from looking at this imperfect approximation of "pure" capitalism (and as we argued in section F.8, it is the "quasi" aspects of the system that counted in industrialisation, not the laissez-faire ones).

So, was 19th century America stable? No, it most definitely was not.

Firstly, throughout that century there were a continual economic booms and slumps. The last third of the 19th century (often considered as a heyday of private enterprise) was a period of profound instability and anxiety. Between 1867 and 1900 there were 8 complete business cycles. Over these 396 months, the economy expanded during 199 months and contracted during 197. Hardly a sign of great stability (since the end of world war II, only about a fifth of the time has spent in periods of recession or depression, by way of comparison). Overall, the economy went into a slump, panic or crisis in 1807, 1817, 1828, 1834, 1837, 1854, 1857, 1873, 1882, and 1893 (in addition, 1903 and 1907 were also crisis years).

Part of this instability came from the eras banking system. "Lack of a central banking system," writes Richard Du Boff, "until the Federal Reserve act of 1913 made financial panics worse and business cycle swings more severe" [Accumulation and Power, p. 177] It was in response to this instability that the Federal Reserve system was created; and as Doug Henwood notes "the campaign for a more rational system of money and credit was not a movement of Wall Street vs. industry or regional finance, but a broad movement of elite bankers and the managers of the new corporations as well as academics and business journalists. The emergence of the Fed was the culmination of attempts to define a standard of value that began in the 1890s with the emergence of the modern professionally managed corporation owned not by its managers but dispersed public shareholders." [Wall Street, p. 93] Indeed, the Bank of England was often forced to act as lender of last resort to the US, which had no central bank.

In the decentralised banking system of the 19th century, during panics thousands of banks would hoard resources, so starving the system for liquidity precisely at the moment it was most badly needed. The creation of trusts was one way in which capitalists tried to manage the system's instabilities (at the expense of consumers) and the corporation was a response to the outlawing of trusts. "By internalising lots of the competitive system's gaps -- by bring more transactions within the same institutional walls -- corporations greatly stabilised the economy." [Henwood, Op. Cit., p. 94]

All during the hey-day of laissez faire we also find popular protests against the money system used, namely specie (in particular gold), which was considered as a hindrance to economic activity and expansion (as well as being a tool for the rich). The Individualist Anarchists, for example, considered the money monopoly (which included the use of specie as money) as the means by which capitalists ensured that "the labourers . . . [are] kept in the condition of wage labourers," and reduced "to the conditions of servants; and subject to all such extortions as their employers . . . may choose to practice upon them", indeed they became the "mere tools and machines in the hands of their employers". With the end of this monopoly, "[t]he amount of money, capable of being furnished . . . [would assure that all would] be under no necessity to act as a servant, or sell his or her labour to others." [Lysander Spooner, A Letter to Grover Cleveland, p. 47, p. 39, p. 50, p. 41] In other words, a specie based system (as desired by many "anarcho"-capitalists) was considered a key way of maintaining wage labour and exploitation.

Interestingly, since the end of the era of the Gold Standard (and so commodity money) popular debate, protest and concern about money has disappeared. The debate and protest was in response to the effects of commodity money on the economy -- with many people correctly viewing the seriously restrictive monetary regime of the time responsible for economic problems and crisis as well as increasing inequalities. Instead radicals across the political spectrum urged a more flexible regime, one that did not cause wage slavery and crisis by reducing the amount of money in circulation when it could be used to expand production and reduce the impact of slumps. Needless to say, the Federal Reserve system in the USA was far from the institution these populists wanted (after all, it is run by and for the elite interests who desired its creation).

That the laissez-faire system was so volatile and panic-ridden suggests that "anarcho"-capitalist dreams of privatising everything, including banking, and everything will be fine are very optimistic at best (and, ironically, it was members of the capitalist class who lead the movement towards state-managed capitalism in the name of "sound money").

¡°That¡¯s a big honor,¡± commented Larry. ¡°The passenger, while they were high up, threw something and hit the pilot, the seaplane went out of control, the man jumped¡ªand then cut free his parachute, cut the sack holding the emeralds, and hid in the swamp.¡± ¡°I see a light,¡± Sandy said as the airplane swung far out over the dark water. ¡°A green light, but the hydroplane wouldn¡¯t carry lights.¡± "No, no; it's a good deal, but it ain't too much. Not that it could be more, very well," he added, and he glanced furtively at the woman within, who had stretched out on the lounge with her face to the wall. Mrs. Taylor was fanning her. But though the 21st of January was to be the day of the grand attack on the Ministry, the battle was not deferred till then. Every day was a field-day, and the sinking Minister was dogged step by step, his influence weakened by repeated divisions, and his strength worn out by the display of the inevitable approach of the catastrophe. The first decided defeat that he suffered was in the election of the Chairman of Committees. The Ministerial candidate, Giles Earle, was thrown out by a majority of two hundred and forty-two to two hundred and thirty-eight, and the Opposition candidate, Dr. Lee, was hailed by a shout that rent the House. Other close divisions followed. The fall of Walpole was now certain, and he would have consulted both his dignity and comfort in resigning at once. This was the earnest advice of his friends, but he had been too long accustomed to power to yield willingly. He was oppressed with a sense of his defeats, and the insolence of enemies whom he had so long calmly looked down upon without fear. He was growing old and wanted repose, but he still clung convulsively to his authority, though he had ceased to enjoy it. "Should think they was bride and groom, if they wasn't so old." "March them right over to that shed there," said the Major, "and the Quartermaster will issue them muskets and equipments, which you can turn over again when you reach Chattanooga. Good-by. I hope you'll have a pleasant trip. Remember me to the boys of the old brigade and tell them I'll be with them before they start out for Atlanta." The train finally halted on a side-track in the outskirts of Chattanooga, under the gigantic shadow of Lookout Mountain, and in the midst of an ocean of turmoiling activity that made the eyes ache to look upon it, and awed every one, even Si and Shorty, with a sense of incomprehensible immensity. As far as they could see, in every direction, were camps, forts, intrenchments, flags, hordes of men, trains of wagons, herds of cattle, innumerable horses, countless mules, mountains of boxes, barrels and bales. Immediately around them was a wilderness of trains, with noisy locomotives and shouting men. Regiments returning from veteran furlough, or entirely new ones, were disembarking with loud cheering, which was answered from the camps on the hillsides. On the river front steamboats were whistling and clanging their bells. "Go out and git you a rebel for yourself, if you want to know about 'em," Shorty had snapped at the Orderly. "There's plenty more up there on the hill. It's full of 'em." "Drat 'em! durn 'em!" "He's dead," said Realf. Should you leave me too, O my faithless ladie!" The odds were generally on Reuben. It was felt that a certain unscrupulousness was necessary to the job, and in that Backfield had the advantage. "Young Realf wudn't hurt a fly," his champions had to acknowledge. Though the money was with Reuben, the sympathy was mostly with Realf, for the former's dealings had scarcely made him popular. He was a hard man to his customers, he never let them owe him for grain or roots or fodder; his farm-hands, when drunk, spoke of him as a monster, and a not very tender-hearted peasantry worked itself sentimental over his treatment of his children. Caro was frightened, horrified¡ªshe broke free, and scrambled to her feet. She nearly wept, and it was clear even to his muddled brain that her invitation had been merely the result of innocence more profound than that which had stimulated her shyness. Rough seaman though he was, he was touched, and managed to soothe her, for she was too bashful and frightened to be really indignant. They walked a few yards further along the path, then at her request turned back towards Odiam. Calverley reluctantly departed on his mission, cursing the interruption that prevented his enjoying the degradation of his rival, and the baron now inquired whether Holgrave had confessed himself his villein. HoME¹ú¼Ò²úÃâ·ÑÒ»¼¶Ã«¿¨Æ¬ ENTER NUMBET 0017
xudu9.com.cn
suri6.net.cn
www.sgzkw.com.cn
ptcair.com.cn
www.marxay.com.cn
tushi4.com.cn
jigan6.net.cn
shelu3.net.cn
5iabcd.com.cn
ak500.com.cn

欧美激情兽交av 狠狠插衅小说 成人综合幼幼 强奸小姨子黄色小说 波多野结衣逼器 l伦种子 乱伦1综合 男人阴茎人体图片 WWW.1122PB.COM WWW.HHH834.COM WWW.47NH.COM WWW.YNKQN.COM WWW.BBB900.COM WWW.QQLU33.NET WWW.QQKJKL.COM WWW.CCSPT.ORG WWW.55GAOAV.COM WWW.7Y7B.COM WWW.CNBHKJ.COM WWW.0312A.COM WWW.W26UUU.COM WWW.AIP.ORG WWW.DXDXY.COM WWW.JSQHLJ.COM WWW.SHTZ99.COM WWW.3344G.COM WWW.GOMAJI.COM 手机看成人H动漫 seyishu人体艺术 哪些在线av网站可以看 美女巨乳图迅雷 影音先锋资色色导航 高清肥白裸体图片 www257HKcom 人和动物avmp4 www334455com 迷奸漂亮女邻居 欧美成人群交图片库 wwwbu510com 丁香花成人导航 国产77ccrr打五月丁香 淫荡丝袜mm 少女小山雀69Xx 81av·在线视频o191com 3939yt yy6080理论在线宅男日韩福利大全 2017热伦桑拿片 2014免费基地 超碰少女人 森奈奈子青娱乐视频 九九电影网myoukucomwwwhitefgdxrhkeihmcn a片免插件在线观看 玉女修道院 厕所偷拍tiao 直接播放黄色录相一级色相床上做爱完整版 岳母比老婆好中文字幕 安妮贝拉老熟妇性16P 清纯AV色 A∨在线视频 护土夏子的春天 小学生AV910ppcom www4hu58cam3 成人热情激情 7799路com 家庭乱伦加多撸 我xxnxx 亚洲自拍之家的网站 操美鲍 夜夜爱直播视频 一部女生被插jj的完整黄片 亚洲色图1www68elcom wwwwnnn92com WWWbUbUC0川 乱伦尻屁 成人手机网站你懂得 台湾妹娱乐2222vvvv 娟娟系列电影 wwwsese鸡 成人射妹妹影院wwwxx109com domainwww720lucom 华娱激情网 先锋资源av色撸 熟女丝袜AV视频 www123mcmccom av伦理视频免费在线 免费A级毛片 另类性爱群交 乱伦春色卡通动漫 AⅤ动漫天堂 插入小姨的阴户 2017年黄色AaaV兽性感觉视频免费不花钱 漫画美女被插 淫妻交换magnet 操屄影视 台湾美佬下载 食人岛漏胸图片 射小妹 最新普通话成人视频 驱灵师本子 大哥哥妹妹操在线视频wwwkt888comdctbvphmaiicn 啪啪啪爱txt 在线成人电影小说 日韩美女性高表情图 大鸡巴插逼流水水 好屌色53gancom 924eecom 女主大逼淫乱小说 寂寞求插 美美的嫩穴 国产自拍成人版大全迅雷下载地址 爱爱插插的高潮 kk6611 女星hh吧 武侠古典男性同志 成人aⅴ 干妞网免费在钱中文字幕 爱奇艺成人性大片 把肉棒插进心生厌恶的女儿 幼欲影院 gia爷 黄色小说咋下 土逼土逼撸蛋蛋 互奸 国产自拍wwwaa0ecom 大胆美女人体艺术写真套图 大胆人体气式 开心五月天最新电影 人妻性爱哥哥干 优优14岁少女人体艺术 老逼人体艺术 日夜肏屄电影 撸飘飘 母子撸乱 操b网址大全 欧美淫色撸 免费日本电影 欧美肉丝袜熟妇性爱影院 杨永晴ed2k 白嫩漂亮妹妹内射p 2012qiangjianluanlun 大黑吊 操爸爸女儿 强根宝有没有用 免费在线观看日本人av 妹子喜欢我的鸡巴大 oumei熟妇乱伦 日本女优屄香吗 影音先锋 春宫心 伦理小说专区 色青xiaomeimei 乳头人体艺术照 影音先锋日本大奶乳交 吃屎少女 樱井莉亚先锋影院 妹妹汁液 色妹妹成人动漫 xxoopron 在线观看影音先锋2014色色色 国产90后女生爱爱种子 日韩3级片快播电影 爱做爱 伤感带烟的个性签名 黑石塔地图 沂水二手房信息 杨紫的男朋友 我愿逆流而下 最近黄金走势 波多野结衣空使 成人dvd光碟 插幼幼淫网 终于找到她的炮图了12p 成人小说集锦 我和2个女同事做爱 金发美女也用大吊来开包 华人第四色日日色 欧镁色图 WWW98ZKCOM 巨屌日逼 自拍偷拍系列专区 给个黄色图片网站看看 吉吉影音jiuquse 猛插美女私处 乱伦电影删除删除 华为手机美女辣图 男女性爱做爱肛交图片 淫荡小姐 性爱欧美口交淫妻 美女人体写真逼 色四月婷婷网五月天肉文 乱伦无码欧美 www444con 国产夫妻性交视频合集 亚洲色图欧美色图校园纯情快播 河北乱x门四部全集ed2k WWWKARTCOM sesemov 西游记乱乱小说 制服诱惑色妹妹校园春色 有免费的操逼视频吗 美嫩逼逼 好舒服叫床呻吟 哥哥射满妹妹的肚子 拫狠射女优 穴水姐姐撸撸射精 色哥哥妹妹广场 国产自拍网站三级 didi4secom yy111111光棍手机影院黄片三级做爱 闷绝系列漫画 和洋大妈肏屄 女儿与父亲伦欲 找熟女做爱视频 辣妈h视频 外国子撸网站 美女巨乳口交 淫逼逼成人 夜店女郎波野多结衣 VS色色国王 流出淫水 情欲人生禁地 操女家庭教师 网友自怕 21克magnet 第六感bt论坛 经典开心撸亚洲淫乱无码 男人扒女人衣服的电影 亚洲热熟女 xxoo分类 色色男奇米ckplayer 广播电台106.2有声小说 樱井莉亚bthigh123 魔兽世界樱井莉亚 樱井莉亚vagaa bt小泽玛利亚论坛 www.vipshop.com.cn 能用快播看的黄片 网页看黄片 张杰看黄片 韩国网站 极乐岛论坛 狠狠碰在线视频 要你撸 蜜桃95撸管天堂 国产大保健 迅雷 53x成人网 日韩在线第1页小明看视频 天堂鸟社区 magnet 2204bb 天天日东京热 伦理片 国产自拍 箩莉啵啵 前原友纪在线观看 全球最好最牛的看片网站 (完全免费 在线观看 全球语言 搜啥有啥) 网址1 性爱福利公社 秋霞啪啪伦理片 秋霞电影eeuss免费快播 日本一本道最新视频二区 日韩在线观看高清视频福利 我们立足于美利坚合众国 为全球华人 骑兵在线区2012 2018圣爱天堂网 佐山爱家庭老师 magnet 亚洲成八图片天堂 AV147成人 动感之星福利视频高清 非洲美女奶头的视频下载 rosi韩国vip 先锋色丝袜 欧美亚洲日韩无码短视频迅雷下载 女优家庭做爱视频 一级做爱a片免费视频 色老板在线福利小视频 无码 av视频无限看 国产偷窥自拍在线观看混血哥 佳AV国产AV自拍日韩AV视频 秋霞高清在线线观看秋手机版韩国 泰国超碰在线观看视频 调教日记6 番号 李宗全集手机在线观看456 美女国产福利视频大香蕉 2014阿vt天堂网 天天更新影院亚洲图片 2017岛国免费高清无码 早乙女由依在线观看 mp4 卡通动漫av 秋霞电影sseeuu 800av啪啪啪 亚洲东方免费图片 卵蛋网没福利差点信了 空姐AV种子 超碰caoporn任你操 风间由美影音先锋字幕 迪厅 磁力 俄罗斯一级aV大片在级 中出无码无插件 vakaya福利自拍 伦理片∪ 四虎影院紧急通道 聚会的目的3黄片子 美腿黑丝足交视频 www999999kkcom 无码sex视频 木榴影视 国产xxoo网 东京热,嗯, 我要se色 微客录手机在线福利视频在线观看 wwwsao8o8ocom 800在线东方四虎在线视频 女同在线看手机在线 美脚社区o金币踩踏 处女做爱流血种子下载 我被插的狂喷 高桥鸣海番号 色喜 王丹 奇米影影视超碰在线视频 国模人体蜈蚣 任你操AV在线 国产ts人妖视频 pps视频 极品F罩杯二次元狂热少女女生寝室场景视角自拍视频 邪恶3d视频在线看 小女生在h线视频 泄欲哥导航网址 porntub成人直播 亚洲 日韩 在线 制服 17岁日本美女裸体激情视频 做暧暧 图片区小说区香蕉 床震抽插视频 3311ys韩国演艺圈 硬鸡巴操B视频 美女肉棒黄 手机免费观看欧美大片毛片 轮奸路边小骚货干完还一人一泡尿迅雷 爱爱视城 操空姐嫩逼 草妹在线影院 擦腚沟 洪荒魂巫 2016成 人 在线手机版视频 朴妮唛视频最污 最新的一本道082715 吉泽明步 空姐在线 色久久成人影院 日本www929 play088精品视频 成人情影 刘瑞琪空姐门 国产自拍 很紧 啪啪啪露乳头影院 欧洲老年人性爱视频 任你日一色屋 BT亚洲熟女在线播放 87电影院福利成人伦理 自拍BT 西红柿福利直播 骚逼做爱视频福利 四虎影音在线视频 北京屄屄屄屄屄屄屄 苍井男女性交视频 偷拍自拍 颜射 任你干我们只是搬运工 色吧春暖花开|se8|色吧有你 韩国女主播伦理ck在线观看 在线操长筒袜 174cm模特潜规则实录,高喊插的太深了,都到人家子宫了,1080原版 人人看AV官网 琪琪在线狠狠射 欧美性爱a片黑人和金发白人做爱的视频 网友 在线 酒店 国产 天天射日日射体 内射精视频 小说 阿德倩玉雅莉 美尻写真种子 金沙性爱免费视频 加勒比高清日本一区 祥仔aⅴ 八英里 影音先锋 开裆 亚洲 欧美 字幕 制服 13youngtee幼儿tv 好想被你爱夏日彩春 自拍无码 正在播放91大神dr哥 3p m3u8 大美女上厕所各种视频 群啪 小视频 湖力影院 日本专区无码316 有b吗youbbb论坛 宅男福利 视频网站 cacaoporm视线视频 夜草牧场韩漫 nfdm-119磁力下载 feifeishijei 自拍自窥88 瓜皮影院av 狠狠插 magnet 欧洲天堂网 影音资源日本AV映片 羽毛房主题偷拍 色尼姑官方网站下载 2019免费h网站 手机av福利网站导航 四个90后小青年4p 金沙福利 幼女啪啪视频 韩国女生露出胸和鸡鸡视频 操逼网强奸视频 999涩涩 啵啵x影院 免费在线观看av情人视频 久久vs国产免费视频一本道 PPPD-468 JULI 西瓜影音 久久啪啪视频观看 vr自拍 k5qqcom看片 www57w 欧美h片巨无霸 色狼3 bbb991 图片区成人福利 龙泽梦拉磁力 下载 原味小辣椒小视频在线 日处女逼 电车家庭教师苍井空 日本美女艺术照片 huangseyijipianwuzetian 法国超级幼幼女性交片 激情小说换妻在线 欧美色吧我干你 狠狠碰高清无码 我我我877uu 操妹妹狠狠操 饭岛爱被强奸 xinnongfuchengrendianyingwang 跪求不用播放器的a网 嫂子熟女乱伦 少妇性交图25p 黄色视频偷拍自拍 大奥av淫之乱 婷婷五月天四房播客 90侯性交网 美眉掰小穴图 强奸新娘快播 国语luanlun影片 操逼小哥哥 我想看柳岩的屄 束缚av快播 欧美同性毛片 淫色美女张开大腿图平 快播7777av 金品梅做爱照片 偷拍亚洲色图50p 张柏芝美屄 陈佳丽大胆人体图片 国产cenren WWW_AVAV789_COM 吉尺明步最经典的一部 美国骚妇操逼 男人的大阴茎插屄 s80手机电影 台湾成人 812 石家庄高等专科学校 13日本大胆人体艺术 张筱雨魅惑爱人体 黑逼荡妇 大人的裸体番号 插bb电影网 苍井空早期无码 操逼怎样插的最深 淫妻交换删除 就去爱综合 娇妻淫荡色猫av在线视频 色姐姐睡觉小说 有什么y网站能看明星艳照 激情三级乱伦电影 自偷自拍最火郑媛媛 操逼电影丁香 一本和很多韩国女艺人搞到一起的小说 性爱作品展 强奸丝袜女明星妈妈小说 幼女的小屄 爱爱小说乱伦 好av狠狠吸 www510ccam 就爱操我逼 女阴部艺术图片 日本美女的pp 中过女明星的人体艺术照 儿媳妇口交爸爸鸡巴 囗交动态图 人体艺体阴部插图片 成人激情网白白发布 怡红院新主页 欧美最大胆的裸体性感妹妹图片 怎么用手机在线看片子 张柏芝艳照门伦理论坛 苍井操b图片 国语家庭成人视频 谁有mp4小电影下载 joanne李宗瑞av 兽幼网站 成人两性激情五月 小说色综合 少妇漏屄图片 WWW44QQCOM 激情淫荡父女乱伦小说 那那床上大胆艺术 大屄播放 操小妹嫰逼 欧美尻b动态图片 性交淫乱电影 乱伦小说噜一噜 母女妻快播电影 儿子半夜猥亵他熟睡的小姨迅雷 老婆怀孕我和岳母做爱 人体艺术欧美色 日本商炽所潜入 大胆人艺术人生肉图 日本水耙轮图片 快播操逼电影院 寂寞熟女的诱惑种子 幼女恋夜秀场 天天影视自拍偷拍 美女裸体模特 激情肏骚屄图片 色狼tu 王冬瑶视频网站 秋露伦理Av 老熟妇好爽 好吊操在线视频在线观 sRAV美女 3w550yu 干美女网站 精彩的乱伦小说 高中女友小雯辣文网 人妻淫荡长篇小说 涩涩爱图片图图新闻 无需播放器中文字幕αv 3p欧美动态 美州极品丝袜 看看屋艳母 春暖花开雪白女儿乱伦 白富美的美景之屋 周蕙楠最新的奉献 在教室里和老师做爱了19p 青青草设 狠狠草狠狠爽狠狠啪图片 色5阁婷婷五月 考波波网 美女乱伦wwwtb181com 仙女和农夫在线 看奶子直播app 舔b的视频真人夜夜 av综合节目在线观看 叶玉卿被胶带封嘴 农村老头做爱视频自拍 欧美母子奸淫小说 滛乱大家庭系列 最新青楼社区网址 玉足直播平台 我爱看电片app 动画黄色美女露bb htppwww8aame 金8天国美女哥哥干 母女乱伦剧情 无毒成人网址中文字幕 99热ts人妖 婷婷基地婷婷色五月wap83agcom 010各国美女鲍美 漂亮小姨子来访借住一超碰在线视频 mpopoavcomcn www4501cctk60htm selangchengrenwang 另类日本女人 porn姐弟 成人成人片wwwpp558com 日本美女生值器活人展示图 欧洲女郞人体图 毛欢出浆出白浆套图 Av免费播放 ckplayer日韩 色色肉肉伦乱图 手机基地在线国产母子 一本道无玛人与兽 骚女插菊花 偷拍自拍俺也射 gav成人影院 立花里子快播下载 激情艹在线视频 插插黄片 汽车之家 性感妇穴 善良的嫂子中字种子 555dvd版 第九性交电影 美国成年免费网站 狼友基地在线 唐山师范学院官网 母子乱伦3d动画 天天激情mediaweibocn qvodxxoo com乡村成人三级小说 自拍偷窥88title88亚洲图片 床上爱性 骚B爱操操 牛牛免费超碰厕所偷拍 秋霞高清电车痴汉 谁又免费的黄色网站可以看 偷窥自拍国产在线视频 直入骚穴 久久热集百万潮流 hotfreexxxsexvid 啪啪啪20p 久久热超 女同性恋三级片 少妇熟女欧美图片在线视频偷拍自拍人妻乱伦色图 优果网电影在线观看 亚洲色图偷拍自拍美腿丝袜 www224ttcOm 丝袜美腿另类图片 裤衩在线 丝袜制服青青草网站 乱伦尻屁 成人手机网站你懂得 丝袜OL在线 涩涩爱影音先锋视频 开心色色自拍偷怕 另类亚洲激情 av最大网站在线观看 好色520av 婷婷五月天我淫我色 wwwavtb123c0m 日日riripa2016 韩国mm影音 美女艺术摄影 第四色官方网 图片专区亚洲欧美另娄 在线成人3d电影观看 狼友升级 av1区你懂的 男女野战13p 泷泽萝拉预告片快播 操你视频wwwwdz7com 一本道东京电影院 咪咪少妇大香蕉网 91porm手机端 王东magnet 性爱美女30 亚洲av裸模特走秀视频 偷拍网友自拍超碰 熟女人妻乱伦图区 av的qq群 来吧综合网无码av最新 99热这里只有精品视频99999 啊嗯用力嗯好大动态图 av番 爱爱小说magnet 美国人与兽做爱视频 wwwpp645com 午夜av三级片视频在线 高清大图自拍人体写真 擦妹妹之吻 wwwjj14con 日本少妇阴洞写真 我爱日丈母娘骚逼 田野麻衣 黄蓉偷情传 深圳哪里易找到老女人玩视频 国产多毛老太太 夫妻做爱音频 盗摄偷拍自拍a片在线播放 巨乳巨屌 大鸡鸡插美女黑洞图片 濑穴 色五农夫影院 亚州偷拍图 撸撸吧乱伦 韩国女主播朴夏娃视频 女优嫩逼图 2影片白虎 狠狠撸aji为网站 911sebb亚洲色图在线 郑州广播电台小曼 欧美大黑棍pk亚洲美女 快播 操下岗妇女小说 牛仔裤美女视频网盘 oumeirentiyingdao 母ziyinluan 爆乳露点人体艺术 舔足h 日本有哪些内衣模特 黄蓉牟秘密 操妈妈的bb和做爱 好色爸爸插女儿 欧洲最美的屄 偷拍自拍性爱9p 湖南省人民检察院 夏士莲洗发水 广州问题大米 我们一家访问s 上海大众迈腾 淫荡嫩穴草榴 我搞后妈的逼 北京的胖老太太 好看的偷怕女人图片 操女优色图 兽交论坛小说 xb电影网奇米影视 rtys邪恶 WWWAVAVAV5COM 免费成人一级电影 春暖花开性吧欧美动漫 田欣人体艺术欣赏 入屄爽鸡巴 朴曼妮deyanzao 人体奶秀图片图库 我跟处女开苞小说 我爱看片免网页版 播放 偷拍自拍亚洲色图美腿丝袜变态另类 欧美掰阴人体艺术 AV女被群交 日本草b的女人 小妇骚屄诱惑 偷拍高清炮图 七七色狠狠操 肏姐姐屄图片 丝袜足交老师小说 meimvnenxue 干逼色激情电影 开心激情mangent aotu17comwwwaotu17com 做爱乱伦淫水直流 男人与母海豚 大香蕉伊人久草萝莉AV 德国胖老太视频 美国A片乱伦在线观看 五月情包网国语 熟妇福利视频导航 87bbeecpom 女优javhd 五月色色狠撸 百度开心撸 国外成人网ph 在线自拍美女自慰视频wwwweipaiee 250qqcome 抽插怀孕少妇 好屌色qqc 聚百万激情图片之多多影音magnet 女人大屁股草比爽吗 农村老太太性交视屏 手机三级片免费影视在线观看 亚洲丝袜走光图片 深夜福利伦理片电影 非州大鸡巴淫色网 女人下阴人体艺术摄影 陈乔恩合成王国贴吧 嘻嘻女大人体艺术 心春色 解禁樱井莉亚 小泽玛利亚电影ftp h网游游戏 谁有手机黄网啊 快播东京热影院 东京热男 国产黄色小说 护士黄色小说 音羽レオン 插妹妹爽图 我要插逼逼 额来撸 撸网站 肉片成人 太郎的幸福生活3d观看 男女男国产AV免费看无码 在线wwwffff15con 巨人影院 美国大黄a1片免费 舌尖舔逼视屏 台湾佬在线视频 国产成年人网址 某航空公司空姐与男友酒店激情 青青草人人懆aomenxinpujing 秋霞电影手机vi版 性爱福利公社 热の中文lu3555 御姐里番 日韩ar无吗免费 樱井步 骑乘 有故事情节的番号 AV521永久地址 明星换脸视频影院 琪琪国产自拍 x4yycom xo动画版 琪琪色原网暴风影音 变态m女在线电影 耽美粗大侵犯骑木马 苍老师av作品 西瓜影音 小萝莉A 午夜欧美 亚洲a片小视频 猫咪无码资源 magnet 明星被强奸种子 ed2k 一一级毛片录像直播室直播 近亲相奸大作战番号 成人 acg 长腿美女丝袜福利视频 色色视频成人导航 微拍福利秋霞 校花福利视频 gav成人免 98影院播在线 韩国演艺圈卖洷悲惨事在线 sao521 免费中出视频在线 成人向网站 久草在线首页老司机 一级黄色毛片红番闵 失忆av番号 mmm178 老女人小树林偷拍视频 西野翔 夫目前犯 正在播放 av研究院 老炮色 色偷偷351 3837dy MIDE-454在线 男人AV皇宫 磁力链 下载 rki435 男人天堂·手机版在线观看 超碰人人干人人射 张萌橙的视频在线观看 秋霞…26uuu 金瓶双艳 粤语 大香蕉青青免费视频 床半逐个数百度云最近 国产站街女偷拍视频 用春药的女主播磁力 巨乳王瑞儿在线视频 抖阴成人 空姐黄色网站做爱视频 自拍偷拍 p 爆乳女神网红猫女王视频 a v淘宝在线观看 暮光之城1免费版视频pp www,EEE,,119cOn 丝袜磁力 下载 最新一本道dvd高清视频 黄色录像国产 688成人 骚熟女肛交图片 91秦先生琪琪 mp4 欧美,日韩av无码海量资源 中国福利视频导航 欧美tv色无极在线影院 操任你操 破初系列在线观看网站 va午夜男人 小明看片 欧美性交m3u8 8x8x福利视频2018最新版そ 成人性爱在线免费视频 唯一试看萝莉免费视频 黑人巨大vs白鸟寿美礼 连裤袜女秘密电影 91青青草地 亚洲系列手机视频 欧美成人野狗免费视频 国产女浴室在线 t先生 卫校 磁力链接 男鸡巴抽插视频 日本好色妻 外国色色的视频网站 神马影院脱衣剧情 纱奈 下载 国产偷拍无码影院 女主播直播影音先锋 G国产自拍 av床戏在线播放 黒木いくみ饮尿 方祺媛 演过的电影 美国xⅩX图 m2e5图片 在线视频 四虎影院av xoxoxoxoxoxo福利 性交视频新影院 性感空姐啪啪啪 小老弟av影院 性爱动态肉h 写真福利 福利车站 m,yyxf2017,com 老女人乱伦黄色电影大全 月夜影院av 大话腐女 演员表 东方影库正确地址域名 日韩缴情综合在线视频 日韩新片Av一手机版 韩国无码迅雷种子下载 性感韩国美女主播叫床 色a∨在线 国语对白偷拍自拍毛片 台湾佬宝贝综合网 男人同性视频在线观看 - 百度 悠悠影院靠 小黄漫画软件 操大奶子骚逼视频 波多野结衣的丝袜在线电影 马牛叉电影 MIBD-799 影院成人体验区 免费va在线网站丁香五月天 射丝袜漫画 淫淫色播 色avba av洗澡 ssshaodizhivideo 夫妻成人无码视频 1百度云盘在线播放 中国teen 嫩模福利宅男影院视频 亚洲 在线 电影院 西瓜成人版有毛黄视频 FSET-532 揉捏唔 周防雪子家庭教师 手机毛片免费无毒播放 一道本日本无码视频在线播放 小黄福利 安土结无码 mp4 夜生活小视频 肏处女屄射精视频 苍井空在线毛钱 国产现社会美女影院 很纯很暧昧改编陈伟 音影先峰app 天天操哥操天天拍天天干 seMMZZ 黑冰女王sm698 成人做爱小视频一丝不挂 4388xx2 绀野光视频 去色876 把96年白嫩美臀小情人带到宾馆肆意蹂躏穿衣服照样操 网红原味小辣椒VIP视频 拈花网电影 今日六月丁香 近亲相姦无码中文字幕 耄耋视频亚洲 SNIS一481 看看 国产自拍林采缇视频在线观看 亚欧偷拍网友视频 明星国产自拍 影音先锋 在线 国产 日韩 自拍 四方色影 蓝色导航最全面准确中立纯粹的导航 完美看看 黑鸡巴视频粗 啪啪啪日屁淫片 华夏成人影院午夜 日本av免费视频观看 29p午夜影院 5床上视频免费 蝌蚪国产 快手成人在线视频 x'x'x'x'x'x'x'x少妇 成人免费视频 A片 肛塞 呻吟 自拍34p 【2017久草福利资源站合集】久草新时代3视频精品 9494自拍在线福利视频 韩国成人教育无码 72rr 你发个一级黄片 juisewang hmgl丝袜系列番号 四虎影库955nn 大大香蕉芝大香蕉首页 曰本啪啪啪漫画AA 亚洲AV在线播放 开心激情网在线观看 五月天tt 久久国产av侧所自慰偷拍 亞洲在綫AV 红色裙子女孩被轮奸视频迅雷下载 magnet 诱奸乱伦幼女 优优生值器艺术 谁有艳照的网站 研依裸体艺术 亚洲亚色图 他色了 打屁股2升级版 大奶骚货掰开16p 91自拍视频网盘 偷偷yin WWW_49979_COM 大几八色色网 法庭篇肛交 黑人夫妇宾馆作爱视频 操逼小说123 欧美人像顶级大胆人体艺术 含苞欲放父女狂欢