As explained in the last section, capitalism will suffer from a boom-and-bust cycle due to objective pressures on profit production, even if we ignore the subjective revolt against authority by working class people. It is this two-way pressure on profit rates, the subjective and objective, which causes the business cycle and such economic problems as "stagflation." However, for supporters of the free market, this conclusion is unacceptable and so they usually try to explain the business cycle in terms of external influences rather than those generated by the way capitalism works. Most pro-"free market" capitalists blame government intervention in the market, particularly state control over money, as the source of the business cycle. This analysis is defective, as will be shown below.
It should be noted that many supporters of capitalism ignore the "subjective" pressures on capitalism that we discussed in section C.7.1. In addition, the problems associated with rising capital investment (as highlighted in section C.7.3) are also usually ignored, because they usually consider capital to be "productive" and so cannot see how its use could result in crises. This leaves them with the problems associated with the price mechanism, as discussed in section C.7.2.
The idea behind the "state-control-of-money" theory of crises is that interest rates provide companies and individuals with information about how price changes will affect future trends in production. Specifically, the claim is that changes in interest rates (i.e. changes in the demand and supply of credit) indirectly inform companies of the responses of their competitors. For example, if the price of tin rises, this will lead to an expansion in investment in the tin industry, so leading to a rise in interest rates (as more credit is demanded). This rise in interest rates lowers anticipated profits and dampens the expansion. State control of money stops this process (by distorting the interest rate) and so results in the credit system being unable to perform its economic function. This results in overproduction as interest rates do not reflect real savings and so capitalists over-invest in new capital, capital which appears profitable only because the interest rate is artificially low. When the rate inevitably adjusts upwards towards its "real" value, the invested capital becomes unprofitable and so over-investment appears. Hence, according to the argument, by eliminating state control of money these negative effects of capitalism would disappear.
Before discussing whether state control of money is the cause of the business cycle, we must point out that the argument concerning the role of the interest rate does not, in fact, explain the occurrence of over-investment (and so the business cycle). In other words, the explanation of the business cycle as lying in the features of the credit system is flawed. This is because it is not clear that the relevant information is communicated by changes in interest rates. Interest rates reflect the general aggregate demand for credit in an economy. However, the information which a specific company requires is about the over-expansion in the production of the specific good they produce and so the level of demand for credit amongst competitors, not the general demand for credit in the economy as a whole. An increase in the planned production of some good by a group of competitors will be reflected in a proportional change in interest rates only if it is assumed that the change in demand for credit by that industry is identical with that found in the economy as a whole.
There is no reason to suppose such an assumption is true, given the different production cycles of different industries and their differing needs for credit (in both terms of amount and of intensity). Therefore, assuming uneven changes in the demand for credit between industries reflecting uneven changes in their requirements, it is quite possible for over-investment (and so over-production) to occur, even if the credit system is working as it should in theory (i.e. the interest rate is, in fact, accurately reflecting the real savings available). The credit system, therefore, does not communicate the relevant information, and for this reason, it cannot be the case that the business cycle can be explained by departure from an "ideal system" (i.e. laissez-faire capitalism).
Therefore, it cannot be claimed that removing state-control of money will also remove the business-cycle. However, the arguments that the state control of money do have an element of truth in them. Expansion of credit above the "natural" level which equates it with savings can and does allow capital to expand further than it otherwise would and so encourages over-investment (i.e. it builds upon trends already present rather than creating them). While we have ignored the role of credit expansion in our comments above to stress that credit is not fundamental to the business cycle, it is useful to discuss this as it is an essential factor in real capitalist economies. Indeed, without it capitalist economies would not have grown as fast as they have. Credit is fundamental to capitalism, in other words.
There are two main approaches to the question of eliminating state control of money in "free market" capitalist economics -- Monetarism and what is often called "free banking." We will take each in turn (a third possible "solution" is to impose a 100% gold reserve limit for banks, but as this is highly interventionist, and so not laissez-faire, simply impossible as there is not enough gold to go round and has all the problems associated with inflexible money regimes we highlight below, we will not discuss it).
Monetarism was very popular in the 1970s and is associated with the works of Milton Friedman. It is far less radical that the "free banking" school and argues that rather than abolish state money, its issue should be controlled. Friedman stressed, like most capitalist economists, that monetary factors are the important feature in explaining such problems of capitalism as the business cycle, inflation and so on. This is unsurprising, as it has the useful ideological effect of acquitting the inner-workings of capitalism of any involvement in such problems. Slumps, for example, may occur, but they are the fault of the state interfering in the economy. This is how Friedman explains the Great Depression of the 1930s in the USA, for example (see his "The Role of Monetary Policy" in American Economic Review, March, 1968). He also explains inflation by arguing it was a purely monetary phenomenon caused by the state printing more money than required by the growth of economic activity (for example, if the economy grew by 2% but the money supply increased by 5%, inflation would rise by 3%). This analysis of inflation is deeply flawed, as we will see.
Thus Monetarists argued for controlling the money supply, of placing the state under a "monetary constitution" which ensured that the central banks be required by law to increase the quantity of money at a constant rate of 3-5% a year. This would ensure that inflation would be banished, the economy would adjust to its natural equilibrium, the business cycle would become mild (if not disappear) and capitalism would finally work as predicted in the economics textbooks. With the "monetary constitution" money would become "depoliticised" and state influence and control over money would be eliminated. Money would go back to being what it is in neo-classical theory, essentially neutral, a link between production and consumption and capable of no mischief on its own.
Unfortunately for Monetarism, its analysis was simply wrong. Even more unfortunately for both the theory and vast numbers of people, it was proven wrong not only theoretically but also empirically. Monetarism was imposed on both the USA and the UK in the early 1980s, with disastrous results. As the Thatcher government in 1979 applied Monetarist dogma the most whole-heartedly we will concentrate on that regime (the same basic things occurred under Reagan as well).
Firstly, the attempt to control the money supply failed, as predicted in 1970 by the radical Keynesian Nicholas Kaldor (see his essay "The New Monetarism" in Further Essays on Applied Economics, for example). This is because the money supply, rather than being set by the central bank or the state (as Friedman claimed), is a function of the demand for credit, which is itself a function of economic activity. To use economic terminology, Friedman had assumed that the money supply was "exogenous" and so determined outside the economy by the state when, in fact, it is "endogenous" in nature (i.e. comes from within the economy). This means that any attempt to control the money supply will fail. Charles P. Kindleburger comments:
"As a historical generalisation, it can be said that every time the authorities stabilise or control some quantity of money. . . in moments of euphoria more will be produced. Or if the definition of money is fixed in terms of particular assets, and the euphoria happens to 'monetise' credit in new ways that are excluded from the definition, the amount of money defined in the old way will not grow, but its velocity will increase. . .fix any [definition of money] and the market will create new forms of money in periods of boom to get round the limit." [Manias, Panics and Crashes, p. 48]
The experience of the Thatcher and Reagan regimes indicates this well. The Thatcher government could not meet the money controls it set -- the growth was 74%, 37% and 23% above the top of the ranges set in 1980 [Ian Gilmore, Dancing With Dogma, p. 22]. It took until 1986 before the Tory government stopped announcing monetary targets, persuaded no doubt by its inability to hit them. In addition, the variations in the money supply also showed that Milton Friedman's argument on what caused inflation was also wrong. According to his theory, inflation was caused by the money supply increasing faster than the economy, yet inflation fell as the money supply increased. As the moderate conservative Ian Gilmore points out, "[h]ad Friedmanite monetarism. . . been right, inflation would have been about 16 per cent in 1982-3, 11 per cent in 1983-4, and 8 per cent in 1984-5. In fact . . . in the relevant years it never approached the levels infallibly predicted by monetarist doctrine." [Op. Cit., p. 52] From an anarchist perspective, however, the fall in inflation was the result of the high unemployment of this period as it weakened labour, so allowing profits to be made in production rather than in circulation (see section C.7.1). With no need for capitalists to maintain their profits via price increases, inflation would naturally decrease as labour's bargaining position was weakened by massive unemployment. Rather than being a purely monetary phenomena as Friedman claimed, it is a product of the profit needs of capital and the state of the class struggle.
It is also of interest to note that even in Friedman's own test of his basic contention, the Great Depression of 1929-33, he got it wrong. Kaldor noted pointed out that "[a]ccording to Friedman's own figures, the amount of 'high-powered money'. . . in the US increased, not decreased, throughout the Great Contraction: in July 1932, it was more than 10 per cent higher than in July, 1929. . . The Great Contraction of the money supply . . . occurred despite this increase in the monetary base." [Op. Cit., pp. 11-12] Other economists also investigated Friedman's claims, with similar result -- "Peter Temin took issue with Friedman and Schwartz from a Keynesian point of view [in the book Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression?]. He asked whether the decline in spending resulted from a decline in the money supply or the other way round. . . [He found that] the money supply not only did not decline but actually increased 5 percent between August 1929 and August 1931. . . Temin concluded that there is no evidence that money caused the depression between the stock market crash and. . . September 1931." [Charles P. Kindleburger, Op. Cit., p. 60]
In other words, causality runs from the real economy to money, not vice versa, and fluctuations in the money supply results from fluctuations in the economy. If the money supply is endogenous, and it is, this would be expected. Attempts to control the money supply would, of necessity, fail and the only tool available would take the form of raising interest rates. This would reduce inflation, for example, by depressing investment, generating unemployment, and so (eventually) slowing the growth in wages. Which is what happened in the 1980s. Trying to "control" the money supply actually meant increasing interest rates to extremely high levels, which helped produce the worse depression since the end of the war (a depression which Friedman notably failed to predict).
Given the absolute failure of Monetarism, in both theory and practice, it is little talked about now. However, in the 1970s it was the leading economic dogma of the right -- the right which usually likes to portray itself as being strong on the economy. It is useful to indicate that this is not the case. In addition, we discuss the failure of Monetarism in order to highlight the problems with the "free banking" solution to state control of money. This school of thought is associated with the "Austrian" school of economics and right-wing libertarians in general (we also discuss this theory in section F.10.1). It is based on totally privatising the banking system and creating a system in which banks and other private companies compete on the market to get their coins and notes accepted by the general population. This position is not the same as anarchist mutual banking as it is seen not as a way of reducing usury to zero but rather as a means of ensuring that interest rates work as they are claimed to do in capitalist theory.
The "free banking" school argues that under competitive pressures, banks would maintain a 100% ratio between the credit they provide and the money they issue with the reserves they actually have (i.e. market forces would ensure the end of fractional reserve banking). They argue that under the present system, banks can create more credit than they have funds/reserves available. This pushes the rate of interest below its "natural rate" (i.e. the rate which equates savings with investment). Capitalists, mis-informed by the artificially low interest rates invest in more capital intensive equipment and this, eventually, results in a crisis, a crisis caused by over-investment ("Austrian" economists term this "malinvestment"). If banks were subject to market forces, it is argued, then they would not generate credit money, interest rates would reflect the real rate and so over-investment, and so crisis, would be a thing of the past.
This analysis, however, is flawed. We have noted one flaw above, namely the problem that interest rates do not provide sufficient or correct information for investment decisions. Thus relative over-investment could still occur. Another problem follows on from our discussion of Monetarism, namely the endogenous nature of money and the pressures this puts on banks. The noted post-keynesian economist Hyman Minsky created an analysis which gives an insight into why it is doubtful that even a "free banking" system would resist the temptation to create credit money (i.e. loaning more money than available savings). This model is often called "The Financial Instability Hypothesis."
Let us assume that the economy is going into the recovery period after a crash. Initially firms would be conservative in their investment while banks would lend within their savings limit and to low-risk investments. In this way the banks do ensure that the interest rate reflects the natural rate. However, this combination of a growing economy and conservatively financed investment means that most projects succeed and this gradually becomes clear to managers/capitalists and bankers. As a result, both managers and bankers come to regard the present risk premium as excessive. New investment projects are evaluated using less conservative estimates of future cash flows. This is the foundation of the new boom and its eventual bust. In Minsky's words, "stability is destabilising."
As the economy starts to grow, companies increasingly turn to external finance and these funds are forthcoming because the banking sector shares the increased optimism of investors. Let us not forget that banks are private companies too and so seek profits as well. Providing credit is the key way of doing this and so banks start to accommodate their customers and they have to do this by credit expansion. If they did not, the boom would soon turn into slump as investors would have no funds available for them and interest rates would increase, thus forcing firms to pay more in debt repayment, an increase which many firms may not be able to do or find difficult. This in turn would suppress investment and so production, generating unemployment (as companies cannot "fire" investments as easily as they can fire workers), so reducing consumption demand along with investment demand, so deepening the slump.
However, due to the rising economy bankers accommodate their customers and generate credit rather than rise interest rates. In this way they accept liability structures both for themselves and for their customers "that, in a more sober expectational climate, they would have rejected." [Minsky, Inflation, Recession and Economic Policy, p. 123] The banks innovate their financial products, in other words, in line with demand. Firms increase their indebtedness and banks are more than willing to allow this due to the few signs of financial strain in the economy. The individual firms and banks increase their financial liability, and so the whole economy moves up the liability structure.
However, eventually interest rates rise (as the existing extension of credit appears too high) and this affects all firms, from the most conservative to the most speculative, and "pushes" them up even higher up the liability structure (conservative firms no longer can repay their debts easily, less conservative firms fail to pay them and so on). The margin of error narrows and firms and banks become more vulnerable to unexpected developments, such a new competitors, strikes, investments which do not generate the expected rate of return, credit becoming hard to get, interest rates increase and so on. In the end, the boom turns to slump and firms and banks fail.
The "free banking" school reject this claim and argue that private banks in competition would not do this as this would make them appear less competitive on the market and so customers would frequent other banks (this is the same process by which inflation would be solved by a "free banking" system). However, it is because the banks are competing that they innovate -- if they do not, another bank or company would in order to get more profits. This can be seen from the fact that "[b]ank notes. . . and bills of exchange. . . were initially developed because of an inelastic supply of coin" [Kindleburger, Op. Cit., p. 51] and "any shortage of commonly-used types [of money] is bound to lead to the emergence of new types; indeed, this is how, historically, first bank notes and the chequing account emerged" [Kaldor, Op. Cit., p. 10]
This process can be seen at work in Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations. Scotland in Smith's time was based on a competitive banking system and, as Smith notes, they issued more money than was available in the banks coffers:
"Though some of those notes [the banks issued] are continually coming back for payment, part of them continue to circulate for months and years together. Though he [the banker] has generally in circulation, therefore, notes to the extent of a hundred thousand pounds, twenty thousand pounds in gold and silver may frequently be a sufficient provision for answering occasional demands." [The Wealth of Nations, pp. 257-8]
In other words, the competitive banking system did not, in fact, eliminate fractional reserve banking. Ironically enough, Smith noted that "the Bank of England paid very dearly, not only for its own imprudence, but for the much greater imprudence of almost all of the Scotch [sic!] banks." [Op. Cit., p. 269] Thus the central bank was more conservative in its credit generation than the banks under competitive pressures! Indeed, Smith argues that the banking companies did not, in fact, act in line with their interests as assumed by the "free banking" school:
"had every particular banking company always understood and and attended to its own particular interest, the circulation never could have been overstocked with paper money. But every particular baking company has not always understood and attended to its own particular interest, and the circulation has frequently been overstocked with paper money." [Op. Cit., p. 267]
Thus we have reserve banking plus bankers acting in ways opposed to their "particular interest" (i.e. what economics consider to be their actual self-interest rather than what the bankers actually thought was their self-interest!) in a system of competitive banking. Why could this be the case? Smith mentions, in passing, a possible reason. He notes that "the high profits of trade afforded a great temptation to over-trading" and that while a "multiplication of banking companies. . . increases the security of the public" by forcing them "to be more circumspect in their conduct" it also "obliges all bankers to be more liberal in their dealings with their customers, lest their rivals should carry them away." [Op. Cit., p. 274, p. 294]
Thus "free banking" is pulled in two directions at once, to accommodate their customers while being circumspect in their activities. Which factor prevails would depend on the state of the economy, with up-swings provoking liberal lending (as described by Minsky). Moreover, given that the "free banking" school argues that credit generation produces the business cycle, it is clear from the case of Scotland that competitive banking does not, in fact, stop credit generation (and so the business cycle, according to "Austrian" theory). This also seemed the case with 19th century America, which did not have a central bank for most of that period -- "the up cycles were also extraordinary [like the busts], powered by loose credit and kinky currencies (like privately issued banknotes)." [Doug Henwood, Wall Street, p. 94]
Most "free banking" supporters also argue that regulated systems of free banking were more unstable than unregulated. Perhaps this is the case, but that implies that the regulated systems could not freely accommodate their customers by generating credit and the resulting inflexible money regime created problems by increasing interest rates and reducing the amount of money available, which would result in a slump sooner rather than later. Thus the over supply of credit, rather than being the cause of the crisis is actually a symptom. Competitive investment also drives the business-cycle expansion, which is allowed and encouraged by the competition among banks in supplying credit. Such expansion complements -- and thus amplifies -- other objective tendencies towards crisis, such as over-investment and disportionalities.
In other words, a pure "free market" capitalist would still have a business cycle as this cycle is caused by the nature of capitalism, not by state intervention. In reality (i.e. in "actually existing" capitalism), state manipulation of money (via interest rates) is essential for the capitalist class as it is more related to indirect profit-generating activity, such as ensuring a "natural" level of unemployment to keep profits up, an acceptable level of inflation to ensure increased profits, and so forth, as well as providing a means of tempering the business cycle, organising bailouts and injecting money into the economy during panics. If state manipulation of money caused the problems of capitalism, we would not have seen the economic successes of the post-war Keynesian experiment or the business cycle in pre-Keynesian days and in countries which had a more free banking system (for example, nearly half of the late 19th century in the US was spent in periods of recession and depression, compared to a fifth since the end of World War II).
It is true that all crises have been preceded by a speculatively-enhanced expansion of production and credit. This does not mean, however, that crisis results from speculation and the expansion of credit. The connection is not causal in free market capitalism. The expansion and contraction of credit is a mere symptom of the periodic changes in the business cycle, as the decline of profitability contracts credit just as an increase enlarges it.
Paul Mattick gives the correct analysis:
"[M]oney and credit policies can themselves change nothing with regard to profitability or insufficient profits. Profits come only from production, from the surplus value produced by workers. . . The expansion of credit has always been taken as a sign of a coming crisis, in the sense that it reflected the attempt of individual capital entities to expand despite sharpening competition, and hence survive the crisis. . . Although the expansion of credit has staved off crisis for a short time, it has never prevented it, since ultimately it is the real relationship between total profits and the needs of social capital to expand in value which is the decisive factor, and that cannot be altered by credit." [Economics, Politics and the Age of Inflation, pp. 17-18]
In short, the apologists of "free market" capitalism confuse the symptoms for the disease.
Where there is no profit to be had, credit will not be sought. While extension of the credit system "can be a factor deferring crisis, the actual outbreak of crisis makes it into an aggravating factor because of the larger amount of capital that must be devalued." [Paul Mattick, Economic Crisis and Crisis Theory, p. 138] But this is also a problem facing private companies using the gold standard, as advocated by right-wing Libertarians (who are supporters of "free market" capitalism and banking). The money supply reflects the economic activity within a country and if that supply cannot adjust, interest rates rise and provoke a crisis. Thus the need for a flexible money supply (as desired, for example, by the US Individualist Anarchists). As Adam Smith pointed out, "the quantity of coin in every country is regulated by the value of the commodities which are to be circulated by it: increase that value and . . . the additional quantity of coin requisite for circulating them [will be found]." [Op. Cit., p. 385]
Token money came into being because commodity money proved to be too inflexible for this to occur, as "the expansion of production or trade unaccompanied by an increase in the amount of money must cause a fall in the price level. . . Token money was developed at an early date to shelter trade from the enforced deflations that accompanied the use of specie when the volume of business swelled. . . Specie is an inadequate money just because it is a commodity and its amount cannot be increased at will. The amount of gold available may be increased by a few per cent a year, but not by as many dozen within a few weeks, as might be required to carry out a sudden expansion of transactions. In the absence of token money business would have to be either curtailed or carried on at very much lower prices, thus inducing a slump and creating unemployment." [Karl Polyani, The Great Transformation, p. 193]
To sum up, "[i]t is not credit but only the increase in production made possible by it that increases surplus value. It is then the rate of exploitation which determines credit expansion." [Paul Mattick, Economics, Politics and the Age of Inflation, p. 18] Hence token money would increase and decrease in line with capitalist profitability, as predicted in capitalist economic theory. But this could not affect the business cycle, which has its roots in production for capital (i.e. profit) and capitalist authority relations, to which the credit supply would obviously be tied, and not vice versa.
If state control of credit does not cause the business cycle, does that
mean Keynesianism capitalism can work? Keynesian economics, as opposed
to free market capitalism, maintains that the state can and should intervene
in the economy in order to stop economic crises from occurring. The
post-war boom presents compelling evidence that it can be effect the
business cycle for the better by reducing its impact from developing into
a full depression.
The period of social Keynesianism after the war was marked by reduced
inequality, increased rights for working people, less unemployment, a
welfare state you could actually use and so on. Compared to present-day
capitalism, it had much going for it. However, Keynesian capitalism is still
capitalism and so is still based upon oppression and exploitation. It was, in
fact, a more refined form of capitalism, within which the state intervention
was used to protect capitalism from itself while trying to ensure that working
class struggle against it was directed, via productivity deals, into
keeping the system going. For the population at large, the general idea
was that the welfare state (especially in Europe) was a way for society
to get a grip on capitalism by putting some humanity into it. In a confused
way, the welfare state was supported as an attempt to create a society in
which the economy existed for people, not people for the economy.
While the state has always had a share in the total surplus value produced
by the working class, only under Keynesianism is this share increased
and used actively to manage the economy. Traditionally, placing checks on
state appropriation of surplus value had been one of the aims of classical
capitalist thought (simply put, cheap government means more surplus value
available for capitalists to compete for). But as capital has accumulated,
so has the state increased and its share in social surplus (for control over
the domestic enemy has to be expanded and society protected from the
destruction caused by free market capitalism).
Indeed, such state intervention was not totally new for "[f]rom its origins,
the United States had relied heavily on state intervention and protection for
the development of industry and agriculture, from the textile industry in the
early nineteenth century, through the steel industry at the end of the century,
to computers, electronics, and biotechnology today. Furthermore, the same has
been true of every other successful industrial society." [World Orders,
Old and New, p. 101]
The roots of the new policy of higher levels and different forms of state
intervention lie in the Great Depression of the 1930s and the realisation
that attempts to enforce widespread reductions in money wages and costs
(the traditional means to overcome depression) were impossible because
the social and economic costs would have been too expensive. A militant
strike wave involving a half million workers occurred in 1934,
with factory occupations and other forms of militant direct action
commonplace.
Instead of attempting the usual class war (which may have had revolutionary
results), sections of the capitalist class thought a new approach was
required. This involved using the state to manipulate credit in order to
increase the funds available for capital and to increase demand by state
orders. As Paul Mattick points out:
State intervention can, in the short term, postpone crises by stimulating
production. This can be seen from the in 1930s New Deal period under Roosevelt
when the economy grew five years out of seven compared to it shrinking
every year under the pro-laissez-faire Republican President Herbert Hoover
(under Hoover, the GNP shrank an average of -8.4 percent a year, under
Roosevelt it grew by 6.4 percent). The 1938 slump after 3 years of growth
under Roosevelt was due to a decrease in state intervention:
With the success of state intervention during the second world war,
Keynesianism was seen as a way of ensuring capitalist survival. The
resulting boom is well known, with state intervention being seen as the
way of ensuring prosperity for all sections of society. Before the Second
World War, the USA (for example) suffered eight depressions, since the war
there has been none (although there has been periods of recession). There
is no denying that for a considerable time, capitalism has been able to
prevent the rise of depressions which so plagued the pre-war world and
that this was accomplished by government interventions.
This is because Keynesianism can serve to initiate a new prosperity and
postpone crisis by the extension of credit. This can mitigate the conditions
of crisis, since one of its short-term effects is that it offers private
capital a wider range of action and an improved basis for its own efforts
to escape the shortage of profits for accumulation. In addition, Keynesianism
can fund Research and Development in new technologies and working methods
(such as automation), guarantee markets for goods as well as transferring
wealth from the working class to capital via taxation and inflation.
In the long run, however, Keynesian "management of the economy by means of
monetary and credit policies and by means of state-induced production must
eventually find its end in the contradictions of the accumulation process."
[Paul Mattick, Op. Cit., p. 18]
So, these interventions did not actually set aside the underlying
causes of economic and social crisis. The modifications of the capitalist
system could not totally countermand the subjective and objective limitations
of a system based upon wage slavery and social hierarchy. This can be seen
when the rosy picture of post-war prosperity changed drastically in the 1970s
when economic crisis returned with a vengeance, with high unemployment
occurring along with high inflation. This soon lead to a return to a more
"free market" capitalism with, in Chomsky's words, "state protection and
public subsidy for the rich, market discipline for the poor." This process,
and its effects, are discussed in the next two sections.
Basically, the subjective and objective limitations to Keynesianism we
highlighted in the last section were finally reached in the early 1970s.
Economic crisis returned with massive unemployment accompanied with high
inflation, with the state interventions that for so long kept capitalism
healthy making the crisis worse. In other words, a combination of social
struggle and a lack of surplus value available to capital resulted in the
breakdown of the successful post-war consensus.
The roots and legacy of this breakdown in Keynesianism is informative and
worth analysing. The post-war period marked a distinct change for capitalism,
with new, higher levels of state intervention. So why the change? Simply put,
because capitalism was not a viable system. It had not recovered from the
Great Depression and the boom economy during war had obviously contrasted
deeply with the stagnation of the 1930s. Plus, of course, a militant working
class, which has put up with years of denial in the struggle against
fascist-capitalism would not have taken lightly to a return to mass
unemployment and poverty. So, politically and economically a change was
required. This change was provided by the ideas of Keynes, a change which
occurred under working class pressure but in the interests of the ruling
class.
The mix of intervention obviously differed from country to country, based
upon the needs and ideologies of the ruling parties and social elites. In
Europe nationalisation was widespread as inefficient capital was taken
over by the state and reinvigorated by state funding and social spending
more important as Social Democratic parties attempted to introduce reforms.
Chomsky describes the process in the USA:
Over time, social Keynesianism took increasing hold even in the USA, partly
in response to working class struggle, partly due to the need for popular
support at elections and partly due to "[p]opular opposition to the Vietnam
war [which] prevented Washington from carrying out a national mobilisation. . .
which might have made it possible to complete the conquest without harm to
the domestic economy. Washington was forced to fight a 'guns-and-butter' was
to placate the population, at considerable economic cost." [Noam Chomsky,
Op. Cit., pp. 157-8]
Social Keynesianism directs part of the total surplus value to workers
and unemployed while military Keynesianism transfers surplus value from
the general population to capital and from capital to capital. This allows
R&D and capital to be publicly subsidised, as well as essential but
unproductive capital to survive. As long as real wages did not exceed a
rise in productivity, Keynesianism would continue. However, both functions
have objective limits as the transfer of profits from successful capital to
essential, but less successful, or long term investment can cause a crisis
is there is not enough profit available to the system as a whole. The
surplus value producing capital, in this case, would be handicapped due
to the transfers and cannot respond to economic problems with freely as
before.
This lack of profitable capital was part of the reason for the collapse
of the post-war consensus. In their deeply flawed 1966 book, Monopoly
Capital, radical economists Baran and Sweezy point out that "[i]f
military
spending were reduced once again to pre-Second World War proportions the
nation's economy would return to a state of profound depression" [p. 153]
In other words, the US economy was still in a state of depression,
countermanded by state expenditures (for a good, if somewhat economic,
critique of Baran and Sweezy see Paul Mattick's "Monopoly Capital" in
Anti-Bolshevik Communism).
In addition, the world was becoming economically "tripolar," with a revitalised
Europe and a Japan-based Asian region emerging as major economic forces. This
placed the USA under increased pressure, as did the Vietnam War. However,
the main reason for its breakdown was social struggle by working people. The
only limit to the rate of growth required by Keynesianism to function is
the degree to which final output consists of consumption goods for the
presently employed population instead of investment. And investment is the
most basic means by which work, i.e. capitalist domination, is imposed.
Capitalism and the state could no longer ensure that working class struggles
could be contained within the system.
This pressure on US capitalism had an impact in the world economy and was
also accompanied by general social struggle across the world. This struggle
was directed against hierarchy in general, with workers, students, women,
ethnic groups, anti-war protesters and the unemployed all organising successful
struggles against authority. This struggle attacked the hierarchical core of
capitalism as well increasing the amount of income going to labour, resulting
in a profit squeeze (see section C.7) creating an
economic crisis.
In other words, post-war Keynesianism failed simply because it could not,
in the long term, stop the subjective and objective pressures which capitalism
always faces.
Basically by using, and then managing, the 1970s crisis to discipline the
working class in order to reap increased profits and secure and extend the
ruling classes' power. It did this using a combination of crisis, free markets
and adjusted Keynesianism as part of a ruling elite lead class war against
labour.
In the face of crisis in the 1970s, Keynesianist redirection of profits
between capitals and classes had become a burden to capital as a whole
and had increased the expectations and militancy of working people to
dangerous levels. The crisis, however, helped control working class power
and was latter utilised as a means of saving capitalism.
Initially the crisis was used to justify attacks on working class people
in the name of the free market. And, indeed, capitalism was made more market
based, although with a "safety net" and "welfare state" for the wealthy. We
have seen a partial return to "what economists have called freedom of industry
and commerce, but which really meant the relieving of industry from the
harassing and repressive supervision of the State, and the giving to it
full liberty to exploit the worker, whom was still to be deprived of his
freedom." [Peter Kropotkin, The Great French Revolution, p. 28] The
"crisis of democracy" was overcome and replaced with the "liberty to exploit
human labour without any safeguard for the victims of such exploitation and
the political power organised as to assure freedom of exploitation to the
middle-class." [Op. Cit., p. 30]
Then under the rhetoric of "free market" capitalism, Keynesianism was used
to manage the crisis as it had previously managed the prosperity. "Supply
Side" economics (combined with neo-classical dogma) was used to undercut
working class power and consumption and so allow capital to reap more
profits off working people. Unemployment was used to discipline a militant
workforce and as a means of getting workers to struggle for work instead
of against wage labour. With the fear of job loss hanging over their heads,
workers put up with speedups, longer hours, worse conditions, less safety
protection and lower wages and this increased the profits that could be
extracted directly from workers as well as reducing business costs by allowing
employers to reduce on-job safety and protection and so on. The labour
"market" was fragmented to a large degree into powerless, atomised units with
unions fighting a losing battle in the face of state backed recession. In
this way capitalism could successfully change the composition of demand from
the working class to capital.
This disciplining of the working class resulted in the income going to capital
increasing by more than double the amount of that going to "labour." Between
1979 and 1989, total labour income rose by 22.8%, total capital income rose
by 65.3% and realised capital gains by 205.5%. The real value of a standard
welfare benefit package has also declined by some 26 percent since 1972.
[Edward S. Herman, "Immiserating Growth: The First World", Z Magazine]
And Stanford University economist Victor Fuch estimates that US children
have lost 10-12 hours of parental time between 1960 and 1986, leading to
a deterioration of family relations and values. Unemployment and
underemployment is still widespread, with most newly created jobs
being part-time.
We should point out that the growth in income going to labour includes all
"labour" incomes and as such includes the "wages" of CEOs and high level
managers. As we have already noted, these "wages" are part of the surplus
value extracted from workers and so should not be counted as income to
"labour." The facts of the Reagan fronted class war of the 1980s is that
while top management income has skyrocketed, workers wages have remained
usually stable or decreased absolutely. For example, the median hourly wage
of US production workers has fallen by some 13% since 1973 (we are not
implying that only production workers create surplus value or are "the
working class"). In contrast, US management today receives 150 times what the
average worker earns. Unsurprisingly 70% of the recent gain in per capita
income have gone to the top 1% of income earners (while the bottom lost
absolutely). [Chomsky, Op. Cit., p. 141] Income inequality has increased,
with the income of the bottom fifth of the US population falling by 18%,
while that of the richest fifth rose by 8%.
Indirect means of increasing capital's share in the social income were also
used, such as reducing environment regulations, so externalising pollution
costs onto current and future generations. In Britain, state owned
monopolies were privatised at knock-down prices allowing private capital
to increase its resources at a fraction of the real cost. Indeed, some
nationalised industries were privatised as monopolies allowing monopoly
profits to be extracted from consumers for many years before the state allowed
competition in those markets. Indirect taxation also increased, being used
to reduce working class consumption by getting us to foot the bill for
Pentagon-style Keynesianism.
Exploitation of under-developed nations increased with $418 billion being
transferred to the developed world between 1982 and 1990 [Chomsky, Op. Cit.,
p. 130] Capital also became increasingly international in scope, as it used
advances in technology to move capital to third world countries where state
repression ensured a less militant working class. This transfer had the
advantage of increasing unemployment in the developed world, so placing more
pressures upon working class resistance.
This policy of capital-led class war, a response to the successful working
class struggles of the 1960s and 1970s, obviously reaped the benefits it
was intended to for capital. Income going to capital has increased and
that going to labour has declined and the "labour market" has been disciplined
to a large degree (but not totally we must add). Working people have been
turned, to a large degree, from participants into spectators, as required
for any hierarchical system. The human impact of these policies cannot be
calculated. Little wonder, then, the utility of neo-classical dogma to the
elite - it could be used by rich, powerful people to justify the fact that
they are pursuing social policies that create poverty and force children
to die.
As Chomsky argues, "one aspect of the internationalisation of the economy
is the extension of the two-tiered Third World mode to the core countries.
Market doctrine thus becomes an essential ideological weapon at home as
well, its highly selective application safely obscured by the doctrinal
system. Wealth and power are increasingly concentrated. Service for the
general public - education, health, transportation, libraries, etc. -
become as superfluous as those they serve, and can therefore be limited
or dispensed with entirely." [Year 501, p. 109]
The state managed recession has had its successes. Company profits are
up as the "competitive cost" of workers is reduced due to fear of job
losses. The Wall Street Journal's review of economic performance
for the last quarter of 1995 is headlined "Companies' Profits Surged 61%
on Higher Prices, Cost Cuts." After-tax profits rose 62% from 1993, up
from 34% for the third quarter. While working America faces market forces,
Corporate America posted record profits in 1994. Business Week
estimated 1994 profits to be up "an enormous 41% over [1993]," despite
a bare 9% increase in sales, a "colossal success," resulting in large
part from a "sharp" drop in the "share going to labour,"
though "economists say labour will benefit -- eventually."
[cited by Noam Chomsky, "Rollback III",Z Magazine,
April 1995]
Moreover, for capital, Keynesianism is still goes on as before, combined
(as usual) with praises to market miracles. For example, Michael Borrus,
co-director of the Berkeley Roundtable on the International Economy (a
corporate-funded trade and technology research institute), cites a 1988
Department of Commerce study that states that "five of the top six fastest
growing U.S. industries from 1972 to 1988 were sponsored or sustained,
directly or indirectly, by federal investment." He goes on to state
that the "winners [in earlier years were] computers, biotechnology, jet
engines, and airframes" all "the by-product of public spending."
[cited by Chomsky, World Orders, Old and New, p. 109]
As James Midgley points out, "the aggregate size of the public sector did
not decrease during the 1980s and instead, budgetary policy resulted in a
significant shift in existing allocations from social to military and law
enforcement." ["The radical right, politics and society",
The Radical Right and the Welfare State, Howard Glennerster and
James Midgley (eds.), p. 11]
Indeed, the US state funds one third of all civil R&D projects, and the UK
state provides a similar subsidy. [Chomsky, Op. Cit., p. 107] And
after the widespread collapse of Savings and Loans Associations in deregulated
corruption and speculation, the 1980s pro-"free market" Republican
administration happily bailed them out, showing that market forces were
only for one class.
The corporate owned media attacks social Keynesianism, while remaining
silent or justifying pro-business state intervention. Combined with
extensive corporate funding of right-wing "think-tanks" which explain why
(the wrong sort of) social programmes are counter-productive, the corporate
state system tried to fool the population into thinking that there is no
alternative to the rule by the market while the elite enrich themselves
at the publics expense.
So, social Keynesianism has been replaced by Pentagon Keynesianism cloaked
beneath the rhetoric of "free market" dogma. Combined with a strange
mix of free markets (for the many) and state intervention (for the select
few), the state has become stronger and more centralised and "prisons also
offer a Keynesian stimulus to the economy, both to the construction business
and white collar employment; the fastest growing profession is reported to
be security personnel." [Chomsky, Year 501, p. 110]
While working class resistance continues, it is largely defensive, but, as
in the past, this can and will change. Even the darkest night ends with
the dawn and the lights of working class resistance can be seen across
the globe. For example, the anti-Poll Tax struggle in Britain against the
Thatcher Government was successful as have been many anti-cuts struggles
across the USA and Western Europe, the Zapatista uprising in Mexico is
inspiring and there has been continual strikes and protests across the
world. Even in the face of state repression and managed economic recession,
working class people are still fighting back. The job for anarchists to is
encourage these sparks of liberty and help them win.
“That’s a big honor,” commented Larry. “The passenger, while they were high up, threw something and hit the pilot, the seaplane went out of control, the man jumped—and then cut free his parachute, cut the sack holding the emeralds, and hid in the swamp.” “I see a light,” Sandy said as the airplane swung far out over the dark water. “A green light, but the hydroplane wouldn’t carry lights.” "No, no; it's a good deal, but it ain't too much. Not that it could be more, very well," he added, and he glanced furtively at the woman within, who had stretched out on the lounge with her face to the wall. Mrs. Taylor was fanning her. But though the 21st of January was to be the day of the grand attack on the Ministry, the battle was not deferred till then. Every day was a field-day, and the sinking Minister was dogged step by step, his influence weakened by repeated divisions, and his strength worn out by the display of the inevitable approach of the catastrophe. The first decided defeat that he suffered was in the election of the Chairman of Committees. The Ministerial candidate, Giles Earle, was thrown out by a majority of two hundred and forty-two to two hundred and thirty-eight, and the Opposition candidate, Dr. Lee, was hailed by a shout that rent the House. Other close divisions followed. The fall of Walpole was now certain, and he would have consulted both his dignity and comfort in resigning at once. This was the earnest advice of his friends, but he had been too long accustomed to power to yield willingly. He was oppressed with a sense of his defeats, and the insolence of enemies whom he had so long calmly looked down upon without fear. He was growing old and wanted repose, but he still clung convulsively to his authority, though he had ceased to enjoy it. "Should think they was bride and groom, if they wasn't so old." "March them right over to that shed there," said the Major, "and the Quartermaster will issue them muskets and equipments, which you can turn over again when you reach Chattanooga. Good-by. I hope you'll have a pleasant trip. Remember me to the boys of the old brigade and tell them I'll be with them before they start out for Atlanta." The train finally halted on a side-track in the outskirts of Chattanooga, under the gigantic shadow of Lookout Mountain, and in the midst of an ocean of turmoiling activity that made the eyes ache to look upon it, and awed every one, even Si and Shorty, with a sense of incomprehensible immensity. As far as they could see, in every direction, were camps, forts, intrenchments, flags, hordes of men, trains of wagons, herds of cattle, innumerable horses, countless mules, mountains of boxes, barrels and bales. Immediately around them was a wilderness of trains, with noisy locomotives and shouting men. Regiments returning from veteran furlough, or entirely new ones, were disembarking with loud cheering, which was answered from the camps on the hillsides. On the river front steamboats were whistling and clanging their bells. "Go out and git you a rebel for yourself, if you want to know about 'em," Shorty had snapped at the Orderly. "There's plenty more up there on the hill. It's full of 'em." "Drat 'em! durn 'em!" "He's dead," said Realf. Should you leave me too, O my faithless ladie!" The odds were generally on Reuben. It was felt that a certain unscrupulousness was necessary to the job, and in that Backfield had the advantage. "Young Realf wudn't hurt a fly," his champions had to acknowledge. Though the money was with Reuben, the sympathy was mostly with Realf, for the former's dealings had scarcely made him popular. He was a hard man to his customers, he never let them owe him for grain or roots or fodder; his farm-hands, when drunk, spoke of him as a monster, and a not very tender-hearted peasantry worked itself sentimental over his treatment of his children. Caro was frightened, horrified—she broke free, and scrambled to her feet. She nearly wept, and it was clear even to his muddled brain that her invitation had been merely the result of innocence more profound than that which had stimulated her shyness. Rough seaman though he was, he was touched, and managed to soothe her, for she was too bashful and frightened to be really indignant. They walked a few yards further along the path, then at her request turned back towards Odiam. Calverley reluctantly departed on his mission, cursing the interruption that prevented his enjoying the degradation of his rival, and the baron now inquired whether Holgrave had confessed himself his villein. HoME国家产免费一级毛卡片
ENTER NUMBET 0017 C.8.1 Does this mean that Keynesianism works?
"The additional production made possible by deficit financing does appear
as additional demand, but as demand unaccompanied by a corresponding increase
in total profits. . . [this] functions immediately as an increase in
demand that stimulates the economy as a whole and can become the point
for a new prosperity" if objective conditions allow it. [Economic
Crisis and Crisis Theory, p. 143]
"The forces of recovery operating within the depression, as well as the
decrease in unemployment via public expenditures, increased production up
to the output level of 1929. This was sufficient for the Roosevelt
administration to drastically reduce public works. . . in a new effort to
balance the budget in response to the demands of the business world. . . The
recovery proved to be short-lived. At the end of 1937 the Business Index
fell from 110 to 85, bring the economy back to the state in which it had
found itself in 1935. . . Millions of workers lost their jobs once again."
[Paul Mattick, Economics, Politics and the Age of Inflation, p. 138]
C.8.2 What happened to Keynesianism in the 1970s?
"Business leaders recognised that social spending could stimulate the
economy, but much preferred the military Keynesian alternative - for
reasons having to do with privilege and power, not 'economic rationality.'
This approach was adopted at once, the Cold War serving as the justification.
. . . The Pentagon system was considered ideal for these purposes. It extends
well beyond the military establishment, incorporating also the Department of
Energy. . . and the space agency NASA, converted by the Kennedy administration
to a significant component of the state-directed public subsidy to advanced
industry. These arrangements impose on the public a large burden of the
costs of industry (research and development, R&D) and provide a guaranteed
market for excess production, a useful cushion for management decisions.
Furthermore, this form of industrial policy does not have the undesirable
side-effects of social spending directed to human needs. Apart from unwelcome
redistributive effects, the latter policies tend to interfere with managerial
prerogatives; useful production may undercut private gain, while
state-subsidised waste production. . . is a gift to the owner and manager,
to whom any marketable spin-offs will be promptly delivered. Social
spending may also resource public interest and participation, thus enhancing
the threat of democracy. . . The defects of social spending do not taint
the military Keynesian alternative. For such reasons, Business Week
explained, 'there's a tremendous social and economic difference between
welfare pump-priming and military pump-priming,' the latter being far
preferable." [World Orders, Old and New, pp. 100-101]
C.8.3 How did capitalism adjust to the crisis in Keynesianism?
yuri2.net.cn
roxsh.com.cn
www.wed99.com.cn
www.yylogos.com.cn
www.cuia.org.cn
www.sadyal.com.cn
www.pchsz.com.cn
savion.com.cn
www.nasuo5.net.cn
www.neima7.net.cn